Scandinavian Political Studies, Bind 9 (New Series) (1986) 3

Party Organizational Elites in Norwegian Politics Representativeness and Party Democracy*

Knut Heidar, University of Oslo

Side 279

In this research note I shall present a picture of Norwegian party organizational elites. We know of course that these elites will not in important respects mirror the general population. All research on political elites shows a social distortion (Putnam 1976). The more interesting question is how large the social gap is and whether the parties in their elite composition still present us with a picture of the major cleavages in Norwegian politics. One aspect of elite representativeness, singled out for particular treatment is the influx of women into the party elites The data presented here were collected through questionnaires to organizational office holders in all parliamentary parties (1981-1985).l In September 1984 the members of the elected national party bodies - usually labelled the central committee(7-23 and the national committee (16-51 members) - and the salaried political secretaries at the national headquarters and in the county parties received a mail questionnaire with 243 variables. 390 people in the Norwegian Labour Party (DNA), the Conservative Party (H), the Christian People's Party (Kr. F.), the Centre Party (SP), the Socialist Left Party (SV) and the Liberal Party (V) were approached and by November 318 or 82% had answered. The highest return among these 'national party elites' was achieved for the Christian People's Party with 90%; lowest was the Conservative Party with 74%. During the spring of 1985 these parties held important national congresses

Resumé

The question raised is why 'secondary' representativeness of political elites, i.e. the degree of similarity in socio-demographic background between elite and electorate, is considered important in debates on democratic polities. Three answers are considered: to improve long-term 'primary' representativity, i.e. the representation of public opinions; to build systemic legitimacy; and to encourage the participation of low-mobilized groups. From this perspective new data on the party organizational elites in Norway are presented: The party elites are socially skewed in terms of present position, but fairly broad based in terms of parental background. They reflect the traditional cleavage structures of Norwegian politics, even though the high shares of women and public employees indicate potentially emerging cleavage structures. Particularly the women in party positions are disproportionately from the lower ranks of the public job market.



*The material of this research note was first presented and discussed at the ECPR workshop on Internal Arenas in Gothenburg, April 1986, directed by S. Berglund and J. Sundberg.

Side 280

in preparation for the Storting election of September 1985. The delegates - the 'middle-level elites' in politics (Cayrol & Reif, eds. 1986) - also received a questionnaire with identical or equivalent questions. Altogether 1252 delegates were approached and 935 or 75% returned the questionnaire. The representativity of the material was - as far as it was possible to check - very good both for the national and the middle-level elites (Heidar 1985a, Heidar 1985b). In the following I shall - if not otherwise explicitly stated - present the total material, that is the national and the 'mid-elites' of the party organizations together (n=1253, 76% of the group approached).

Representativity and Party Democracy

Party representativeness is central to interest articulation and legitimacy in liberal democratic polities.2 The theory of democratic party government is based on the premiss of party representativeness. The citizens will in periodic elections be asked to choose between party candidates for public offices and between party/ candidate programmes. Two requirements distinguish 'responsible' parties from other political groups: They put forward candidates for elections and they offer policies for a broad range of issues within the public domain. The party representatives represent the electorate in the process of government. But representation' clearly mean different things (Pitkin 1967, Birch 1971). In democratic it is primarily interests that are to be represented, or to be more precise, interests as seen by people themselves, their views and attitudes, or in other words their opinions. As for other characteristics - economic position, occupation, sex, place of residence, race, etc. - the literature is more ambivalent in its appetite for representativeness. Most constitutional arrangements, however, some form of spatial representativeness. Corporate theories advocate representation. The women's movement asks for sex quotas. Ethnic and other minorities claim special protection in the form of quotas or other constitutional safeguards. The premiss is that these characteristics are seen as politically important in the sense that attitudes, interests, views will (or ought to) follow from them. In addition, educational reasons are voiced: Group representation the elite level will encourage participation of particular sections of the population and mould the democratic potential of the polity as a whole.

But if majority opinions are the official compass course of democratic systems, why do journalists, political scientists and, most important, the politicians themselvesdraw to social representativeness, to the sex bias, to age and whatever is considered important within a particular political setting? We can approach an answer by making a distiction between 'primary' and 'secondary' representativity, the first being the representativity of views, the second the representativityof socio-demographic background characteristics are consideredpolitically by being attributed an impact on political views -

Side 281

present or future. This secondary representativeness is seen to be democratically important for three reasons: It may encourage participation from low-mobilized groups, it may improve the primary representativity of the political system, and it may contribute to system legitimacy.

Why should secondary representativeness improve the representation of views? First, the choice put before the voters on election day by the parties and candidates is in practice the choice between a few policy packages. Secondary representativeness the future representation of priorities and views not in the forefront of the electroral debates more likely. Second, only in exceptionally stable political settings will no major new issue arise during the electoral term. Third, even in a stable political climate, people do change their minds. Fourth, even the most single-minded politician cannot be expected to act out all his electoral promises as he will not be able to foresee or control all possible outcomes with a bearing on these issues. The list could be made longer. The point, however, is that (although important) election day choices on the basis of individually perceived interests cannot be a sufficient base to secure the 'primary' representativeness of a political system. One will also need a 'fair' representation of attributes known to or considered likely to be associated with the interests of the electorate.

There are two kinds of counter-arguments to this. First, that people's selfperceived ought not to prevail, because they simply don't know their best interests. This is the 'elitist' reaction. The argument has taken many forms but dominant in the post-war tradition has been some version of the Schumpeter thesis that the crux of democracy lies in the electoral choice between competing elites. The incumbent elite will know that their actions will be criticized by an opposition and that their record will be put before the voters in the next election, knowledge that will force the elite to give 'due weight' to popular feelings and at the same time keep the voters away from a task they are not fit to carry out - the day-to-day business of government.

The second counter-argument holds that even if the electorate is not presented with all possible combinations of views on election day, the major interests and general attitudes toward government - present and future - are enclosed inparty ideologies. Ideologies are more robust and durable criteria for electoral choice than the volatile issues at electoral times and can be expected to produce more 'representative' elite views in future 'new' situations. It is, however, a long way from the election day voice of the people and - we may add - from party ideologies,to daily business of politics. But there is also of course an equally hazardous relationship between socio-demographic background characteristics and individual politics. Are factors such as residence, sex, occupation, race, etc. so closely connected to elite political attitudes that increased secondary representativeness will improve the long term representation of political views?3 Could it not be the other way around that demands for secondary representativenessactually diminish rather than improve the representation of

Side 282

self-perceived interests?1 Claims for secondary representativeness are certainly not based on the assumption that it will replace periodic elections or ideological 'package' politics, but is rather viewed as a supplement to fill in the details of democratic politics.

These are major issues in debates on the instrumental task of channelling majority views into government. But political systems are not judged by their channelling capacities alone. Also ability to integrate the public, to produce a feeling of belongingness and participatory spirit - or in other words the legitimacy of political systems - is important. One way to create legitimacy is to make the channels of interest representation work, to secure representativeness of views, to make people feel their interests are presented and considered at the highest political level. But instrumental representativity alone will not suffice. In order to produce acceptance of political decisions made, it may be equally important that the decision-maker is 'one of us'. That we know him or some of his colleagues, or can identify with the 'groups' he represents.

The Law of Increasing Disproportion

No political elite has ever socially mirrored the people under its rule. And the higher it has reached in the pyramid of power, the more exclusive the elite. This is a general observation which also has been established in the empirical research on Norwegian political elites (Hellevik 1969, Higley et al. 1976, Heidar 1974, Lægried & Olsen 1978), even though the exclusiveness of elites in a fairly egalitarian society like Norway appears to be less than in most other pluralist societies (Olsen 1983).

Table 1 makes the point anew for the party organizational elites of Norway. In terms of education, occupation and income, the party elites are far from representative of their supporters. According to official statistics, 57% of the population (above 16 years) had no more than 7-9 years at school (Statistisk Arbok 1985), while only 2% of the party politicians had no education beyond the primary school. 42% had, however, been to college/university compared to 11 % in the general population. Occupational profiles are no less exclusive. 82% of the party elite held white collar positions, a mere 4% were classified as worker/craftsman. while 66% of all personal taxpayers earned less than 90,000 kroner in 1982, only 22% of the party leaders earned that little 1-2 years later. Less than 6% earned more than 150,000, while 26% of the party leaders had an income exceeding 170,000.

Turning to the figures for the national party elites alone (not presented here), we find very little difference from the party elites as a whole. The reason, however,for apparent refutation of the 'general law' of increased exclusiveness, is to be found in the formal rules and recruitment practices established by the parties. These top party bodies are to some extent built on corporate representation

Side 283

DIVL4208

Table 1. Background Characteristics of the Party Elites. Per cent.

Side 284

tion- the women's and youth's organization will have their share, and different
geographical and social considerations are made.

Norwegian political elites are recruited from the higher social strata. However, make up 40% of the party elites in Norway, which in a comparative perspective is extremely high - at least outside the Scandinavian setting (Cayrol & Reif, eds., 1986, Haavio-Mannila, ed. 1983). Another fact that perhaps is not so surprising, but nevertheless very indicative of Norwegian politics, is the broad recruitment base of party elites. In terms of 'father's occupation' social background more varied than present status would lead us to think. More than one half grew up with a father occupied in the primary sector or as a worker/craftsman 38% had their 'roots' in the white collar culture.

Cleavages in Party Recruitment

Stein Rokkan saw six relatively stable 'cleavage lines' in Norwegian politics - one between the geographical centre and the periphery, three cultural (language, religion, and moral) and two economic cleavages (in the labour market and in the consumer market) (Rokkan 1967, 1970, Valen & Rokkan 1974). Although the political trends of the 1970's and 1980's appear to have weakened these structures (Valen & Aardal 1983, Knutsen 1985), one would still expect to trace them in the background of party elites recruited to their party many years ago. Table 1 makes the point vividly. While 49% in the Labour Party had their social origin in the working class, 63% of the agrarian Centre Party experienced a 'primary-sector socialization'. In the Conservative Party, Høyre, 51% grew up with a father in white collar (private)/leading job in civl service/liberal profession or private business and only 9% had a 'worker/craftsman' background. Although less so, there are also differences in the present occupation of the various party elites. We find more workers in Labour and the Left Socialist Party than in other parties, and there are more farmers in the Centre Party and managers/white collar (private) employees in Høyre. But in terms of present occupation there is an additional difference. All parties had a sizable portion of their organizational elite in public jobs. SV and the liberal party had the highest share, while fewer are found in the conservative and agrarian parties. This is not very surprising as the public sector occupied 34% of the work-force in 1984 (Knutsen 1986). The pillar of the post-war state, the Labour Party, had 50% of their central office bearers in state employment. And in Labour an additional 20% were employed within the labour movement, but these figures - for all parties - are inflated by the fact that party secretaries are included in the definition of the national party elite. Even so, 8% of the national conference delegates are employed within the movement in the Labour Party, which is twice the figure of the next party.

Turning to education we find - not surprisingly (Heidar 1974, Haaversen-
Westhassel 1984) - that the Labour elite has less formal education than the

Side 285

Conservative elite. But we also find that the two parties most closely tied to the 'meritocracy' were the left socialists and the liberals. And the highest salaried elite group was in the Conservative Party. Although the relationship between socio-economic variables and party choice has weakened in the electorate, it is still apparent at the level of the party elites.

Women in Party Politics

40% of the party organizational elites were women, an extraordinary rise from their rather modest presence before 1970. At the Labour congress in 1961 13% of all delegates were women. This change is partly due to changes in party statutes: Three parties have now quotas for party offices (Labour, Left Socialist Party and the Liberals). But also parties without such arrangements now have a much higher share of women at all levels than a decade ago. This formidable entry of a new group into politics has naturally stirred public as well as professional - both in terms of 'why?' and 'so what?' (Kirkpatrick 1976, Haavio-Mannila Hellevik & Skard 1985).

Both the reasons why and the question of consequences, however, depend in part on whether this increased group representation actually changes the compositionofthe on any other dimension than sex. Sex in itself may, of course, carry significant political loadings, but do changing sex ratios also lead to other changes in socio-demographic characteristics? In Table 2 on the background of women in party elites, there are few differences from the picture presented for the elite as a whole. By and large the women's background matches that of the men; they reproduce the social cleavages rather than change them. Labour women have to a greater extent a working class background, the women in the Christian People's Party and the Centre Party come disproportionately from the primary sector. The educational level of the party women is somewhat lower than the men's - fewer are educated at colleges and universities. Most interestingly, however,48%of women in party elites had a job in the lower echelons of the public sector - in the schools, the social services, the health sector, etc. In four parties more than half the women worked in this intermediate and lower public sector. Only 20% of the men had a similar job. The men, however, were more likely to hold leading jobs in the public sector. Why is the female party elite disproportionatelyrecruitedfrom public sector? And from a particular level of that sector? Regarding the latter question, different age profiles cannot explain the level at which they are working. In fact the data show that there are virtually no age differences between the groups. The reasons why both men and women are drawn disproportionately from the ranks of the state employed have not been fully elucidated, although the guess that state employment may give better opportunities for political work than most jobs in the private sector is possibly not

Side 286

DIVL4231

Table 2. Background Characteristics of Women in the Party Elites. Per cent.

far off the mark. As for the very high share of women with this background it may also be that state employment makes it less difficult to combine professional work, political interests and a family. Searching along this line in Table 3, however,thereis great difference in parental obligations. Half the party elites have

Side 287

DIVL4234

Table 3. Party Elite with Children under 18 Years of Age According to Party and Sex. Per cent.

one or more children below 18 years. There are differences between the parties, but not immediately transparent ones. In structural terms, then, only the publicprivatedimensionsurvives exploratory effort to find emerging cleavages in the wake of the massive entry of women into party office-holding positions.

Assertions that the 'new' political women are generally young and belong to the educational elite do not hold for the party elites present at the national conferences. But are women as well integrated into party organizational work as their male counterparts? Do they have an easier way to the top than the men? Are they transient party workers or do they plan to stay on? Table 4 suggests that the changing composition of the party organizational elites is not unwarranted. Women spend slightly less time on political work during a 'typical' week - probably due to the fact that they hold fewer public positions than the men. We also find in all parties - although most notably in the Christian People's Party and the Liberal Party - a group of men with conference experience not matched by the women. But considering the rather recent entry of women into the party political elites, there are remarkably few differences in party involvement and activities. As for their plans for future political activity, we also see that women are slightly more inclined to plan an increase in their political involvement. Table 4 also shows a difference between the sexes in their 'involvement profiles'. When asked about whether there were particular political questions that interested them or whether they took an interest in most areas under political discussion, 58% of the men came out as 'generalists', while 58% of the women were self-placed sector-politicians. One can of course debate whether this really is a big difference, but it holds for all parties and fits well an image of 'new-comers' to politics - mobilized through particular issues and not yet(?) generalized through political practice.

Side 288

DIVL4237

Table 4. Party Activities and Interest Profiles of Pary Elites According to Party and Sex. Per cent.

Conclusions

Representativity is essential to a national party democracy. Primarily of course the representation of views, but also representativity in terms of residence, biological social characteristics are asked for. First, in order to secure a broader and more durable representativity of views - i.e. to improve the representativity produced by electoral choice on the basis of campaign issues. Second, to build political legitimacy and, third, to provide participatory incentives to modestly involved groups.

The empirical analysis of the 'national' and 'middle-level' elites of the party organizations reveals, as expected, that we are also dealing with a social elite. The elite as a whole has nevertheless a broad social background as measured by father's occupation. In fact, these different milieus for primary political socializationreflect traditional cleavages in Norwegian politics. There is, on the other

Side 289

hand, a comparatively high proportion of women in the Norwegian party elites. A new and obviously important dimension is also present in the private-public distinction. The public sector is heavily represented in the elites of party politics. And perhaps even more interesting is the fact that so many women are found in the lower public category regardless of party.

Several questions arise from the growth of women and public employees in the party elites. How will it effect the politicians' ability to reflect majority opinions? What are the effects on political mobilization of different groups in society and on the legitimacy of the political system as a whole? How is the system of corporate interest representation effected? Are sex and public vs. private employment supplements or substitutions to the traditional cleavage lines of Norwegian politics? This focus on 'representative' party democracy highlights the need for more firmly based answers.



NOTES

1. With the exception of the Progress Party - Fremskrittspartiet - which held 4 (out of 155) parliamentary in the Storting 1981 -1985 and in the present term holds 2 (out of 157) seats. The party which is a free market, anti-tax party, ordinarily found to the right of the conservatives, did not wish to take part in the project. The Liberal Party - Venstre - which had 2 parliamentarians in the previous Storting (1981-1985) but is now without representation is, however, included.

2. Many works could be referred to at this point. A rather selective list would include King 1969, Rose 1974, Berger 1979, Butler et al. 198i, Pizzorno 1981, von Beyme 1985.

3. There is a large literature on this subject which I shall not go into. It is, however, quite clear that the causal chain between background and political opinions at the elite level is both long and complicated (Eulau & Czudnowski 1976).

4. This has been a central point in much resistance towards quotas. Consider, e.g., the American debate on the Democrat McGovern-Fraser Commission (Kirkpartrick 1976).

REFERENCES

Berger, S. 1979. 'Politics and Antipolitics in Western Europe in the Seventies', Daedalus 48 (winter),
27-50.

von Beyme, K. 1985. Political Parties in Western Democracies. Aldershot: Gower.

Butler, D., Penniman, H. R. & Ranney, A. 1981. Democracy at the Polls. Washington: American
Enterprise Institute.

Cayrol, R. & Reif, K. eds. 1986. Party Conference Delegates in Western Europe. Forthcoming.

Eulau, H. & Czudnowski, M. M. eds. 1976. Elite Recruitment in Democratic Polities. New York:
Sage.

Haaversen-Westhassel, O. 1984. Norsk Eliteforskning. En studie av sammensetningen av sentralstyrene
Høyre, Arbejderpartiet og SF/SV i etterkrigstiden. Universitetet of Oslo, ISV: Hovedoppgave
statsvitenskap.

Haavio-Mannila, E., Dahlerup, D., Eduards, M., Gudmundsdottir, E., Halsaa, 8., Hernes, H. M.,
Hanninen-Salmelin E., Sigmundsdottir, 8., Sinkkonen, S., & Skard T. eds. 1983. Det uferdige
demokratiet. Kvinner i nordiskpolitikk. Oslo: Nordisk Ministerråd.

Heidar, K. 1974. 'Partielite og politikk', Tidsskrift for samfunnsforskning 15, 314-341.

Heidar, K. 1985a. 'Partidemokratiprosjektet. Gjennomføringen av spørreskjemaundersøkelsen med
'den nasjonale partieliten". University of Oslo: Institutt for statsvitenskap.

Heidar, K. 1985b. 'Partidemokratiprosjektet. Gjennomføringen av spørreskjemaundersøkelsen med
landsmøte-delegatene'. University of Oslo: Institutt for statsvitenskap.

Hellevik, O. 1969. Stortinget - en sosial elite? Oslo: Pax.

Hellevik, O. & Skard, T. 1985. Norske kommunestyrer -plassfor kvinner? Oslo: Universitetsforlaget.

Highley, J., Lowell Field, G. & Grøholt, K. \9l6.Elite Structure and Ideology. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget.

King, A. 1969. 'Political Parties in Western Democracies', Polity, (Winter), 111-141.

Kirkpatrick, J. 1975. 'Representation in the American National Conventions: The Case of 1972',
British Journal of Political Science 5, 265-322.

Kirkpatrick, J. 1976. The New Presidential Elite. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

Knutsen, O. 1985. Politiske verdier, konfliktlinjer og ideologi - den norske politiske kulturen i komparativt
University of Oslo: Institutt for statsvitenskap.

Knutsen, O. 1986. 'Sosiale klasser og politiske verdier i Norge', Tidsskrift for samfunnsforskning
27, no. 3.

Lægreid, P. & Olsen, J. P. 1978. Byråkrati og beslutning. Bergen: Universitetsforlaget.

Pitkin, H. F. 1967. The Concept of Representation. Berkeley: University of California Press.

Pizzorno, A. 1981. 'Interests and Parties in Pluralism', in Berger, S. ed. Organizing Interests in
Western Europe. Cambridge: CUP.

Putnam, R. D. 1976. The Comparative Study of Political Elites. New Jersey: Prentice-Hall.

Rokkan, S. 1967. 'Geography, Religion and Social Class. Crosscutting Cleavages in Norwegian
Polities', in Lipset, S. M. & Rokkan, S. eds. Party Systems and Voter Alignment. New York: Free
Press.

Rokkan, S. 1970. Citizens, Elections, Parties. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget.

Valen, H. & Rokkan, S. 1974. 'Norway: Conflict Structure and Mass Politics in a European
Periphery', in Rose, R. ed. Comparative Electoral Behavior. New York: Free Press.

Rose, R. 1974. The Problem of Party Government. Middlesex: Penguin Books.

Valen, H. & Aardal, B. O. 1983. 'The Changing Electoral Basis of Political Parties: The Case of
Norway', Scandinavian Review, 34-42.