Scandinavian Political Studies, Bind 9 (New Series) (1986) 1

Political Institutions, Public Policy and Economic Growth

Jan-Erik Lane & Svante Ersson, University of Umeå

Side 19

Resumé

The argument of the Rise and Decline of Nations (RADON) opens up a new area of important social science research: to understand the social and political setting of economic growth. The paper tests the argument that institutionalization leads to the decline of nations slowing down the rate of economic growth. Employing several indicators on economic growth and controlling for a number of factors the finding with regard to the OECD-nations is that the Olson emphasis on institutionalization is confirmed.

Introduction

There has been for some years now an increased interest in the interaction between and economics. The rapidly expanding literature on the popularity function as well as the politico-business cycle are perhaps the most conspicuous manifestations of this kind. But the theme of the Rise And Decline of Nations (RADON) by Mancur Olson (1982) belongs to the very same type of argument. Equating the rise and decline of nations with their growth rates in the overall economy, Olson ventures to state that the institutional fabric of society is a missing link in traditional theories explaining economic growth. Olson argues that a crucial factor in explaining the rise and decline of nations such as the United Kingdom, the Federal Republic of Germany, France, Sweden, Switzerland Japan is a politically very relevant factor, viz. the structure of pressure groups at various levels of government. These so-called distributional coalitions reduce economic growth by pushing for their special interests, thus bringing about national decline. The wealth of nations is not only a function of economic variables but also of the nature of the political authority structure. What is the relationship between political institutions and economic growth?

Politics and Economic Growth

It is hardly astonishing that politics is mentioned as a potentially relevant explanatory factor when accounting for the variation in growth rates. Economic theory has concentrated on variables like labor, capital and technology (Hahn & Matthews 1964, Ott, Ott & Yoo 1975) which, it seems, may be influenced by political decision-making. Thus, the supply of labor may be augmented by

Side 20

policies that promote immigration, the availability of capital may depend on taxation rules and technological advance may by stimulated by R&D policies. Two different types of models may be suggested in order to take the interaction between politics and economic growth in account. Politics may be singled out as a factor which, in addition to the traditional economic variables, conditions growth rates, or politics may be modelled as a determinant of growth rates by means of its impact on the standard economic variables. Politics may explain what is left to explain after considering economic factors, or politics may be conceived as a determinant of these very same economic variables. The theme in RADON singles out one kind of political factor, political institutions, and the argument is that the structure of these institutions matters very much for economic development. Thus, the RADON argument is reminiscent of the current emphasis on institutionalism (March & Olsen 1984). The more segmentedthe structure in terms of the size and strength of distributional coalitions, the less the economic advance. What matters is not primarily political decision-making, because it is the overall structure of pressure groups in relation to state authority that determines growth rates. This explains the country variationin rates, at least among the rich countries with a mixed economy.

The RADON argument is an attempt to employ the idea of a conflict or tradeoff efficiency and redistribution to explain the variation in growth rates at the national level. Following the argument in his Logic of Collective Action, LCA, Olson (1969) advances a theory consisting of nine theoretical hypotheses focussing on the conflict between overall economic efficiency and growth on the one hand and the interests of distributional coalitions on the other. The nine theoretical propositions are all derived from the argument of the LCA that economic growth is a public good which it is not rational to provide once a group of actors is large. Only small groups will provide collective interests of which public goods is simply one type, because in small groups it is possible to overcome basic difficulties in public goods provision, the free rider problem and the preference revelation problem.

Special interest groups pursue certain kinds of collective interests. What, then, is a collective interest? The basic idea in LCA as well as in RADON is that a collective interest is the same as a public good according to the public finance interpretation. Following on from the identification of a public good as nonexcludability jointness as well as the theory that a collective interest is a public good, for a group the basic Olson model states the minimum condition for the provision of any collective interest:

(1)


DIVL333

where F; is the share of the individual i, V is the gain of the group g from the
provision of a certain level T of the collective interest and C is the cost for

Side 21

the provision. We could safely predict that collective good will be provided as
long as at least the benefit of one individual is larger than the cost of the good.

The Olson equation can be related to a theory about the optimal size of groups in relation to the provision of collective interests. The occurrence of the free rider phenomenon depends upon the possibility to determine the willingness to pay for a collective good (W), which is a function of the size of the group (N). We could have a willingness to a pay function in rank order

(2)


DIVL341

Equation (2) means that the individual who is willing to pay the most for the public good (N = 1) is willing to pay Wo, the next individual (N = 2) is willing to pay Wo • 2a, etc. in decreasing willingness to pay. Then, we have a total or integrated willingness to pay function

<3)


DIVL347

i.e. with a finite number of individuals the total willingness to pay function is, of course, the sum total of all individuals' willingness to pay. However, for simplicity we assume continuity. The cost of providing the good to a group of size N might be modeled as

(4)


DIVL353

which amounts to the most simple model having the property of decreasing cost
per member of the group. Maximizing net benefits for the group means total
willingness to pay minus total costs, i.e.


DIVL357

(5)

First order condition for maximum yields

(6)


DIVL365

and since a is greater than zero it is obvious that the second order condition for maximum is fulfilled. N* is the optimal size of the collective, b is marginal cost and W(0) is the highest willingness to pay recorded. This implies that the optimal size of the collectivity grows with a fall in marginal cost and increases with the individual willingness to pay. Furthermore, the more gently the willingness to

Side 22

pay curve falls, the larger the collectivity. But the larger the group the more rational it becomes to restrict the willingness to pay. Thus, there will be an undersupplyof interests that concern large groups, i.e. economic growth. It is in the interest of each individual to misrepresent his/her willingness to pay in order to become a free rider. Thus, the public good will only be provided voluntarily if:

(7)


DIVL371

Empirical Evidence

Although RADON has stimulated several attempts at testing the theory empirically is difficult to make an overall assessment of the empirical evaluation. It has been argued that the theory has met with empirical corroboration, but also that there are severe counter-instances (Mueller 1983, International Studies Quarterly 1983). Moreover, it has also been claimed that the theory is very difficult to test, and what is even worse, that it is framed in such a way that it cannot refuted. By adding ad hoc hypotheses the RADON argument could always saved. It must be readily admitted that there is no straight forward way of testing the nine hypotheses comprising the core of the argument. Firstly, it is far from clear how some of the concepts are to be measured or observed: What is a distributional coalition? How do we assess the influence and position of such an entity? What are the indicators on encompassing collective interests? Secondly, since economic growth is presumably affected by other factors than the structure of distributional coalitions, how can we devise a model that captures the interaction between all the relevant variables allowing us to state the true partial impact of the institutional structure on economic development? The abstract nature of RADON makes an empirical test of the theory a delicate business. Various tests may be devised, but it is far from clear what their import

is.

What could we reasonably expect if the RADON argument is true? Since it is possible to measure the variation in growth rates among the OECD nations for the post-World War Two period, these data could be employed to test the Olson theory. We would expect to find that if there is a country variation in economic growth, then some measure of the status and position of distributional coalitions would explain at least some of this variation. If, on the other hand, there is no such country variation in growth rates or if political institutions matter very little, then we would be inclined to question the theory.

Looking at the period between 1960 and 1983 the data about growth rates indicate that there is not only a country variation but also a variation over time. Given the emphasis of RADON on the country differences to be explained by political institutionalism we would expect to find that economic growth rates

Side 23

DIVL398

Table 1. Analysis of Variance of GDP-Growth Rates 1961-1983 by Country and Time

differ more between nations than within nations over time. A simple analysis of variance may be employed to test this implication of RADON. As Table 1 shows, the test is negative: it is not the case that the yearly growth rates are more determinedby than by time, meaning that the over time variation is much more pronounced than the between nation differences.

It is worth emphasizing that the within nation differences are far larger than
the between nation differences when it is a matter of the yearly variation in


DIVL401

Table 2. Average Growth Rates in the OECD Nations: 1961-1970,1971-1983,1961-1983 (real GDP), 1960-1981 (real GDP/capita). In percent

Side 24

growth rates. This finding is a warning against any theory that focuses on country as a crucial determinant of economic development. Since the structure of political institutions does not change radically from one year to another, the implication of the finding reported on in Table 1 is clearly that the RADON argument cannot explain that part of the variation in economic growth or decline that is short-run. How about the long-run variation?

Even if the rate of economic growth hovers from one year to another - which cannot be accounted for by the structure of political institutions but perhaps by political decision-making - it may still be the case that the average variation in growth rates displays a clear country identification. Table 2 shows various measures on the long-run variation in economic development.

Bypassing the substantial yearly variations in growth rates, it is possible to identify a stable variation over time. Considering the first time period (1961-70), the average growth rate varies between 10.7% (Japan) and 2.8% (United Kingdom). country variation is not as extensive during the second time period, as the difference between the maximum (Turkey = 5.5%) and the minimum (Switzerland = 1.1%) has gone down. It must be emphasized that the structure of the country variation is only partly the same during the two time periods, as the correlation coefficient indicates (r = .52). This is again a warning against the attempt to identify a stable country variation during the post-War period. There is simply too much variation even between average growth rates over time. However, for the substantial time variation, we may single out four sets of nations that differ in the average growth rate between 1961-1983:

(1) below 3.3%: Denmark, F R Germany, Luxembourg, New Zealand,
Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom and United States;

(2) 3.3.-3.9%: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Italy, Netherlands;
(3) 4.0-4.9%: Canada, Finland, France, Iceland, Ireland and Norway;
(4) over 5.0%: Greece, Japan, Portugal, Spain and Turkey.

How are we to account for this pattern of variation in average growth rates? Let us test a number of models that attempt to account for the long-run variation in economic growth. We will restrict our models by including politically relevant variables in order to search for evidence that politics matter. While in no way suggesting models that would compete with the standard economic growth models, we ask if there is any evidence for the theory that political institutions have an impact on the average growth levels in advanced capitalist democracies.

Model Estimation

Let us specify a data set including a number of indicators tapping some latent
variables to be measured across the OECD nations during the post-World War
Two period, particularly since 1960. The data comprise:

Side 25

(1) Rise and decline of nations: various indicators measuring economic: performance like average growth rates for various periods of time in overall GDP and GDP per capita, allowing for the faet that the quality of the data is not always the same (OECD 1979, 1983, 1984).

(2) Wealth of nations: the level of economic output as a starting point in e.g.
1957, measured by GNP per capita (Russett et al. 1964).

(3) Economic maturity: it may be argued that high rates of economic growth should be found in economies with a rapidly expanding secondary sector, whereas the coming of a tertiary sector would mean a slow down in economic growth. The explanation for this hypothesis is that the potential for productivity increases is far less in the tertiary sector. Thus, we include a measure of the size of the tertiary sector (OECD: Historical Statistics).

(4) Institutionalization: an index developed by Choi which taps the length of the period that a nation has had a political structure intact (Choi 1983). The index has been extended to all OECD nations by additional estimates. It may be complemented by another measure of the age of a nation: a modernization index (Taylor & Hudson 1972).

(5) Structure of interest groups: it is not easy to measure the structure of pressure groups nor to come up with some index that expresses valid generalizations about each and every pressure group. We will focus on the structure of the trade unions: a unionization index (Therborn 1984, Kjellberg Miele 1983, Korpi 1983) and a centralization index (Heady 1970).

(6) Corporatist interest mediation: if trade union structure is not the only dimension in the nature of distributional coalitions, then perhaps the access of pressure groups to political power matters. Corporatist avenues to national decision-making may result in encompassing decision-making: two corporatization indices (Schmitter 1981, Wilensky 1976).

(7) Consociationalism: broad social decision-making would be conducive to encompassing social solutions. Thus we include some indicators that measure the amount of political competition in the composition of government: consociationalism index (Lijphart 1979) and an index of oversized cabinets (Lijphart 1984).

(8) Party government: it seems natural to take the colour of government into account when looking at the trade-off between economic growth and redistribution. a socialist government favors redistribution whereas non-socialist governments emphasize economic growth. We measure the composition of governments in the following way: an index of socialist and bourgeois dominance (Schmidt 1983); government durability (Lijphart 1984).

(9) Public policy: pondering about the interaction between politics and
economic growth one cannot bypass the impact of public policies in a longrun
Since the dependent variable is the average growth rates we

Side 26

test some hypotheses about the effect of long-run public policies. Thus, we include measures of the size of the public sector since 1960: total outlays, transfer payments and final government consumption (OCED: Historical Statistics).

In modeling the relationship between institutional variables and average economic growth, some theoretical guidelines may be suggested. We may single out economic performance as the dependent variable but employ three different indicators: real GDP growth 1961-1970, real GDP growth 1971-1983 and real GDP/capita growth 1960-1981. The substantial over time variation means that the estimates may vary depending on which indicator is used. It is reasonable to expect that the level of economic performance has an impact upon the rate of economic growth. The lower the starting point, the higher the rate of change if there is a process of economic growth. Political variables may have an impact upon economic performance over and above that of the level of economic performance. will test the contribution of each institutional variable in a regression comprising, besides the wealth of nations, the particular institutional in question. A similar stepwise procedure will be used in relation to the other political variables, mainly various indicators on the size of the public sector.

Wealth of Nations

It is not quite clear how a certain level of economic performance relates to the rate of change in economic performance. One may argue that countries at a low level tend to display a low level of economic growth, as they are stuck in poor economic performance. The implication is that rich countries would tend to become richer at a more rapid rate. Simon Kuznets argues along this line in his study of economic growth in a historical perspective (Kuznets 1972). However, the opposite argument seems more plausible in relation to countries that have already reached a certain level of economic performance, as is true of the OECDcountries. one would expect a negative relationship meaning that countries at a lower level of economic output tend to grow more rapidly than countries with a more mature economy. In order to test these two alternative hypotheses, a simple regression was run with economic level in 1957 predicting various measures of economic growth (Table 3).


DIVL442

Table 3. Economic level and Growth Rates

Side 27

It appears that the second hypothesis is the correct one for the OECD nations as there is a considerable connection between economic performance and rates of change in the direction suggested by this second hypothesis. A substantial portion of the variation in growth rates in the sixties and the seventies may be accounted for by the level of economic performance. The high growth rates are to be found among nations at a low level of economic performance: Japan, Greece, Portugal, Spain and Turkey. However, this is hardly a complete explanation even the best model explains less than half of the variation. Thus, a basic economic variable like the level of economic output is clearly relevant to the explanation of growth rates, but what is the contribution of institutional variables? now add each of these structural variables listed above to the simple model relating economic growth to economic level.

Institutionalization

The basic hypothesis in RADON states that the length of the time of institutionalization a negative impact on growth rates. How is institutionalization to be measured? The concept of institutionalization is fairly similar to modernization both refer to the emergence of a more or less constitutionally defined polity based on an industrial economy involving considerable portions of the citizens in political life. What matters in the concept of institutionalization according to the Olson interpretation is the length in time of unbroken institutionalization. the occurrence of major societal disaster abolishing established institutions is of crucial importance in this variable. An index of institutionalization or institutional sclerosis has been developed by Choi in a test of the RADON argument. It is fairly similar to a modernization measure identifying the years of consolidating modernizing leadership. The correlation between the two measures is high, r = —.75. Actually, the Choi index includes the standard modernization measure. Institutionalization may have an impact on economic growth either directly or in terms of its impact om level of economic performance. Since institutionalization refers to an extended period of time it may have an impact on both level and rate of change in economic performance. will test a model comprising both institutional sclerosis arid economic level.


DIVL454

Table 4. Institutionalization, Economic Level and Growth Rates

Side 28

DIVL457

Table 5. Economic Maturity, Institutionalization, Economic Level and Growth Rates

A model that includes institutionalization in addition to economic performance better explanations than a simple economic equation. And the parameter estimates indicate that institutionalization is more important than economic level. Table 4 indicates a positive corroboration of the basic argument in RADON: institutions matter in relation to the rise and decline of nations. The goodness of fit of the model must be characterized as substantial. It may be argued that institutionalization merely measures another economic dimension, viz. the economic maturity of the economy. Testing a model including an index of economic maturity - size of the third sector - does not change the findings (Table 5).

Unionization

Although the argument in RADON concerns all kinds of distributional coalitions, is possible to test some implications concerning the impact of trade unions on economic growth. It is often believed that the mere existence of trade unions has a negative impact on economic growth. Olson adheres to this standard assumption but qualifies it by adding the reverse hypothesis that encompassing trade unions promote economic growth. What is the relationship between trade unionization and economic growth in advanced capitalist societies? will test a model that predicts economic growth by means of trade union organization besides the general level of economic performance.

It appears that the contribution of trade union organization to economic growth is slight when the level of economic performance is taken into account. Although there is an overall negative relationship between trade unionization and economic growth as well as an overall positive relationship between trade union centralization and economic growth, these partial relations are not very strong. The argument about distributional coalitions implies that the relationshipbetween union density and economic growth constitutes a U-shaped curve. Testing this implication for various time periods, we may establish that there is little confirmation of this hypothesis except for the sixties, if the analysis

Side 29

DIVL469

Table 6. Unionization, Institutionalization, Economic Level and Growth Rates

also includes Spain and Portugal with their high unionization within an authoritarian state system. It could be the case that trade union organization has a clearer negative impact on economic growth, but that its partial impact will only be revealed in more complex models.

Other Institutional Factors

It has been argued that trade union strength is only one institutional factor that is of crucial importance in a politico-economic perspective. Thus, we find in the literature a number of hypotheses about the implications of corporatism, consociationalism the type of party government (Castles 1982, Wildavsky 1985). The question we pose is if these factors are equally valid for predicting the variation in growth rates. Thus, we test a number of models predicting various measures of economic growth by means of economic level plus one institutional factor at a time. Table 7 reports only a few of these models, viz. the models with the best goodness of fit.

The finding is that adding other institutional factors like corporatism, consociationalismor
of party government results in very minor changes in the
basic explanatory power of the economic variable. It is clearly the case that

Side 30

DIVL481

Table 7. Institutional Factors, Institutionalization, Economic Level and Growth Rates

economic level matters more for growth rates than these institutional variables. It may be pointed out that corporatist institutions may benefit economic growth, whereas socialist dominance in party governments tends to have the opposite effect as predicted in the standard assumption about socialist governments favoring redistribution. However, it is hardly possible to corroborate any strong hypothesis about the contribution of these institutional factors to economic growth.

Public Policy Variables

According to mainstream economic theory an increase in public expenditure has two opposite consequences for economic growth. Whereas spending on collective semi-collective goods would be conducive to economic growth adding to the infra-structure of society, an increase in transfer payments would have a negative impact favoring distribution ahead of growth. Maybe the variation between OECD countries in terms of average growth rates could be accounted for by means of the variation in basic public sector dimensions: total outlays, final government consumption, and social transfer payments. We test three models predicting economic growth by a combination of economic, institutional and policy variables.

The finding is that political institutions matter more for economic growth rates than the overall structure of public policy. Adding various indicators on the size of the public sector does not change the finding that institutional sclerosis is the best single predictor of average economic growth. The relationships between various policy dimensions and economic growth are hardly strong, but the direction of the interaction is negative. A large public sector is hardly conducive to economic growth.

Side 31

DIVL493

Table 8. Public Policy, Institutionalization, Economic Level and Growth Rates

Conclusion

Economic growth rates are very important for the development of nations. It may not be the only relevant indicator on the rise or decline of nations but its crucial position in determining the fate of nations cannot be doubted. What determines economic growth? Looking beyond economic theory and the standard growth models we may search in less certain domains for the noneconomicfactors condition economic development. The Mancur Olson hypothesis about the impact of social and political institutionalization is a step in this new direction of the research into the interaction between politics and economics. Testing some of the implications of the argument in RADON we find that the length of time of institutionalization matters much for the understandingof

Side 32

DIVL507

Figure 1. Path Analysis

standingofthe variation in national growth rates in the post-War period. We have not been able to corroborate any more specific hypothesis as regards the impact of certain structural variables on economic growth. However, taking into account the interaction between the various factors tested in different models, it seems possible to arrive at a pattern. Fig. 1 presents a path modeling of the crucial variables derived from the regression analysis.

In a model that combines several institutional factors, the finding is that a considerable portion of the country variation in economic development may be accounted for. It appears that if the extent of institutionalization is chosen as the basic variable, then an interpretable pattern shows up. Institutionalization has a strong direct negative impact on economic growth. In addition it influences economic development indirectly by means of its impact on economic level and

Side 33

unionization. Institutionalization is conducive to a high level of economic performancewhich turn has a negative impact on economic growth. Similarly, instititionalization goes together with unionization, which also has a negative impact on economic growth. The relationships between institutionalization and unionization as well as between unionization and economic growth are weak. The interaction as portrayed in the path models is rather stable over time. The model explains somewhat better the first period of time which may depend upon a larger variation in the dependent variable. In particular, the connection betweenunionization economic growth is almost non-existent in the last decade.

Without doubt one of the major hypotheses in RADON has met with empirical confirmation. We may still wish to know more about the very composite variable institutional sclerosis in order to test more specific hypotheses its impact on the rise and decline of nations. Clearly, institutionalization an impact on economic growth besides its indirect effect via economic performance and unionization. What is institutional sclerosis if neither unionization nor wealth account for this finding? Again, it must be emphasized that there is a substantial time variation in economic growth rates which cannot be accounted for by an institutional model. But looking at the average growth rates determining the rise and decline of nations in a long-term perspective, the Olson analysis must be further developed.

REFERENCES

Castles, F.G. ed. 1982. Thelmpact of Political Parties: Politics and Policies in Democratic Capitalist
States. London: Sage.

Choi, K. 1983. A Statistical Test of Olson's Model' in Mueller, D.C. ed., pp. 57-78.

Hahn, F.H. &. Matthews, R.C.O. 1964. 'The Theory of Economic Growth: A Survey', The Economic
Journal 74, 779-902.

Heady, B. 1970. 'Tråde Unions and National Wage Policies', Journal of Politics 32, 407-439.

International Studies Quarterly 1983. Symposium: Mancur Olson on the Rise and Decline of
Nations.

Kjellberg, A. 1983. Facklig organisering i tolv lander. Lund: Arkiv.

Korpi, W. 1983. The Democratic Class Struggle. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.

Kuznets, S. 1972. Economic Growth of Nations: Total Output and Production Structure. Cambridge,
Mass.: Harvard UP.

Lijphart, A. 1979. 'Consociationalism and Federation: Conceptual and Empirical Links', Canadian
Journal of Political Science 21, 499-515.

Lijphart, A. 1984. Democracies. New Haven: Yale UP.

March, J.G. & Olsen, J.P. 1984. 'The New Institutionalism: Organizational Factors in Political Life'.
American Political Science Review 78, pp. 734-749.

Miele, S. ed. 1983. Internationales Gewerkschaftshandbuch. Opladen: Leeske & Budrich.

Olson, M. 1969. The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard UP.

Ott, D.J., Ott., A.F. & Yor J. 1975. Macro-Economic Theory. New York: McGraw-Hill.

Schmidt, M. ed. 1983. Westliche Industrie Gesellschafterv Wirtschaft - Gesellschaft - Politik.
Miinchen: Piper.

Schmitter, PC. 1981. 'Interest Intermediation and Regime Governability in Contemporary Europe
and North America', in Berger, S. ed. Organizing Interests in Western Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge
pp. 285-327.

Taylor, C.L. & Hudson, M. 1972. World Handbook of Social and Political Indicators. 2nd ed. New
Haven: Yale UP.

Therborn, G. 1984. 'The Prospects of Labour and the Transformation of Advanced Capitalism', New
Left Review 145, pp. 5-38.

Wildavsky, A. 1985. 'The Logic of Public Sector Growth', in Lane, J.E. ed. State and Market, London:
Sage, pp. 231-270.

Wilensky, H. 1976. The 'New Corporatism', Centralization and the Welfare State. Beverly Hills: Sage.