Scandinavian Political Studies, Bind 4 (New Series) (1981) 2

Analysis of Structural Variability in Budget-Making

Jan-Erik Lane, Anders Westlund and Hans Stenlund, University of Umeå

Side 127

Resumé

Incrementalism as a decision theory about budget-making is empirically evaluated by
post-war data within the framework of budget-making processes of some Swedish public
authorities. The analysis focuses on the relevance of a structural stability hypothesis
using models for the processes of budget requests and appropriations. This hypothesis is
tested by CUSUM and CUSUMQ tests. The more powerful CUSUMQ test clearly indicates
a rejection of the stability assumption, which implies a need for revised models
based on variability assumptions. These alternative models describing budget-making
processes are estimated by Kalman filtering, an estimation approach designed to allow
for structural variability. The paper shows that the key decision principles of incrementalism
are too crude for the understanding of budget decisions.

The process of public resource allocation may be analyzed in terms of a systems framework, comprising a set of input variables and a set of output variables, and the black box, which connects inputs with outputs. Two main subsets ofinputs are taxes and charges, whereas public consumption and investment on the one hand and transfers on the other constitute the two main subsets of outputs. The black box contains the process through which inputs are transformed into outputs, covering the interactions and resource transactions between the political institutions making up the public sector; of course, the difference between outputs and inputs is the financial saving, which may be positive or negative. Diagram 1 portrays the system of political budgeting.

Side 128

DIVL1746

Diagram 1. The System of Political Budgeting.

The process of public resource allocation may be interpreted as a decisionmaking process; a distinction may be made between income decisions, i.e. decisions concerning taxes, charges, and borrowing, and budget decisions, i.e. decisions with regard to spending items and spending levels. Economists and political scientists have offered a number of suggestions as to v/h&tprinciples govern (should govern) the behavior in the black box; we focus upon one such theory of decision-making, the widely accepted theory of budget-making, incrementalism. Among political scientists it is generally believed that incrementalism is an adequate decision theory that explains budgetary decisions, in particular national budget making. From K. R. Popper we have learnt that a good scientific theory may be scrutinized by means of a severe test, that falsification is an inherent part of the scientific enterprise, and that an attempt at rejection of a theory by means of a severe test is actually what a good theory deserves (Popper, pp. 215-250). Thus, should we end up succeeding in our attempt at falsifying the theory of incrementalism, we still sense that we have only paid our tribute to that theory by worrying about what new theory offers a more promising route to a more adequate understanding of budgetary decisionmaking.

1. Incrementalism as a Decision Theory about Budget

1.1. A general note on incrementalism

Incrementalism is a general theory about decision-making; its assumptions
about the behavior of decision-makers were developed by J. G.

Side 129

March & H. A. Simon in Organizations (1958) and D. Braybrooke & C. Lindblom in A Strategy of Decision (1963) as a critique of the rational model of decision-making or the synoptic conception of problem solving. The postulates of rational decision-making (see e.g. Lindgren 1971, White 1976, Tinbergen 1956), i.e. that

(a) decision-makers command comprehensive knowledge about the decision-making situation, enabling them to divide this situation into three mutually exclusive sets: alternative actions, outcomes, and environmental factors

(b) decision-makers command complete knowledge about the relationship
between actions and outcomes

(c) decision-makers are fully familiar with the values that are relevant in
relation to the alternatives, and decision-makers have complete and
transitive preference functions over the outcomes

(d) the essence of decision-making is the rational calculation of the expected value of various alternatives and the choice of the alternative that maximizes the expected value in each single decision-making situation,

are according to the negative part of the incrementalist argument not true of organizational problem solving (March & Simon, pp. 137-169; Braybrooke & Lindblom, pp. 3-57). The positive part of the incrementalist argument comprises an alternative set of behavioral assumptions, by March and Simon identified as Standard Operating Procedures (SOP) and by Braybrooke and Lindblom as the principles of disjointed incrementalism. In his major work The Politics of the Budgetary Process (1964), A. Wildavsky developed the general theory of incremental decision behavior into a clear and specific theory of budgetary behavior. He accomplished two things, on the one hand adding to the general body of incremental decision theory and on the other stating the case for an analysis of budgetary behavior by means of Scientific Method. In order to establish what the incrementalist theory states about a set of public resource allocation decisions, budget making, we therefore turn only to two classic texts by A. Wildavsky: The Politics of the Budgetary Process and Budgeting (1975). Budget decisions consist of two kinds of decisions: decisions on budget requests vxiådecisions on appropriations. According to Wildavsky decisions on budget requests and decisions on appropriations have the following properties:

(a') Simplification and specialization: analyze programs in their various

Side 130

components, avoid comparisons between programs, adhere to a few
indicators on program behavior and program outcomes.

(b') Testing based on experience: let programs be in force for some time in
order to accumulate a comprehensive and reliable material for
evaluation, weigh different kinds of results against each other.

(c') Satisfying and fragmentation: to suboptimize a certain goal function
in relation to a program instead of aiming at maximizing.

(d') Marginal rate of change and a sequential process: to frame decisions that in all essentials are a repetition of the decisions of the previous year with minor changes, to defend the base, and to arrive at an equitable share in the marginal change.

These properties have been considered most plausible and attractive, but the fundamental question is, of course, what evidence is provided in order that decisions on resource allocation in public finance satisfy the incremental decision theory. Firstly, it should be stated that when it is a matter of public resource allocation the theory has only been developed for budget decisions and only been used to describe the budgetary process. To what extent decisions on taxes and charges satisfy the decision theory has not been discussed. It is true that the knowledge of decision principles in taxation and other forms of public resource mobilization are in need of theoretical and empirical study. Secondly, the evidence in the analyses of incrementalism in budget decisions is of two different kinds: soft data studies of the budget procedure at national level and hard data studies of the budgetary process at various institutional levels within public finance. The soft data analyses have substantiated some notions in incrementalism concerning the strategic game around the process of public resource allocation, of the distribution of roles among different interested parties, of the interaction between politicians, administrators, and organized pressure groups. There are several penetrating soft data analyses of the budgetary process in the incrementalist tradition like H. Heclo's & A. Wildavsky's The Private Government of Public Money (1974), I. Sharkansky'sT/iePo/fV/cj1 of Taxing and Spending (1969), andT. Anton's The Politics of State Expenditure in Illinois (1966). However, the soft data analysis does not give decisive information about if, and to what extent, budget decisions satisfy the decision principles of the theory. The hard data studies give information on this very point.

1.2 The quantitative version of incrementalist theory

In models of decisions on budget requests and of decisions on appropriations

Side 131

Wildavsky in collaboration with O. A. Davis and M. A. H. Dempster
has specified key principles in the incremental decision theory:

(i ) The principle of marginalism: decisions on budget requests always involve a marginal increase of the appropriations or the budget requests of the previous year; decisions on appropriations are always based on a marginal change in relation to the appropriations of the preceding year or the budget requests of the same year.

(ii) The principle of an equitable share: decisions on budget requests are always made on an assumption of a constant change in relation to the appropriations of the previous year; decisions on appropriations are basedon a constant modification of the budget requests or the appropriations of the preceding year.

(iii) The principle of the existence of the base: decisions on budget requests
and decisions on appropriations set out from the existence of a
base identifiable over an interval of time.

And Wildavsky, Davis and Dempster (shortened below to (WDD)) took the step from a mere verbal theorizing about budgetary decision-making to presenting a set of formal models interpreting the decision principles (i), (ii), and (iii). The quantitative models which (WDD) have elaborated for an analysis of the national budgetary process in the USA are all simple, linear, stochastic models (Wildavsky et al. 1971, pp. 350-382). Depending on a hypothetical decision rule, they are either static or dynamic. (WDD)'s arguments for linearity are relatively convincing. However, the specification of the linear model can and should be tested empirically. Such an examination is normally based on a detailed analysis of the observed residual process. The simplicity characterizing (WDD)'s models - all of them are one-relation models with one or a few predetermined variables - is in itself attractive. Simplicity is generally an essential criterion of every process of model building. However, if there is interdependence between the two processes of budget requests and budget appropriations, this should be taken into consideration, particularly in connection with the estimation of parameters. Otherwise there are obvious risks of loss of precision and generally weakened reliability when parameters are estimated.

The behavior equations that are assumed to describe the procedure of
budget requests are as follows:


DIVL1798

(1.1)

Side 132

DIVL1802

(1.2)

or


DIVL1808

(1.3)

where n and at denote budget requests and appropriations respectively at the time t, au denotes structure parameters and ey a random term, representing actual shortcomings in the specification of the model, shortcomings of data etc. Model (1.1) thus corresponds to a budget request behavior where budget requests are dimensioned as a function of the immediately preceding appropriations. In model (1.2) the difference between previous budget requests and appropriations is also taken into account. In model (1.3) finally only preceding budget requests are considered, i.e. the size of the appropriations is assumed not to influence decisions on budget requests directly. In a similar way (WDD) formulate the following alternative, simple, linear behavior models for decisions about appropriations:


DIVL1814

(1.4)


DIVL1818

(1.5)

and


DIVL1824

(1.6)

In the appropriation models (1.4-6), (3ij corresponds to structure parameters and \ih to stochastic error terms. The hypotheses are in (1.4) that appropriations are determined mainly by budget requests, in (1.5) that decisions on appropriations made a certain year also pay regard to the difference of the preceding year between appropriations and budget requests, and in (1.6) finally that decisions on appropriations are related in the first place to the appropriations of the previous year. (Cf. the relations of the budget requests above).

What should the world look like described by means of the models (1.1-6) in order that it may be asserted that budget decisions are made in accordance with the principle of marginalism, the principle of an equitable share, and the principle of the existence of the base? The incremental decision theory is confirmed if an estimation of the parameters of the models results in:

Side 133

(a) a marginal increase or decrease between two years
(b) a constant change over an interval of time

(c) the existence of an unchanged base over an interval of time

Inversely it applies that the incremental decision theory is falsified if the interpretation of the estimation of the parameters does not give these properties. Falsifiability, as Popper has clarified, is a property of a scientific theory; actually the more falsifiable a theory is, the more it says about the world. If (a) and (b) are to be true, the parameter estimation must result in constant or stable parameter estimates; if also (c) is to be true, the parameter estimates must be stable and positive. The assumption of a structural stability is indeed falsifiable.

1.3 The evaluation of incrementalism

The unknown structural parameters ciij and |3y of the models should be estimated on the basis of observed statistics of budget requests and appropriations. It is a self-evident criterion of adequacy that the specification of the models is as correct as possible. It is just as essential that the estimation of the parameters is carried out in a reliable way, i.e. that an appropriate method of estimation is used. This is of particular importance if the specification of the models and perhaps also the data available are impaired by shortcomings. The selection of a method of estimation inappropriate for relevant data can undoubtedly restrict or even eliminate the possibilities of utilizing the results of the quantitative analysis in a fruitful way. Different methods of estimation are based on different assumptions particularly with regard to the properties of the random terms; methods of estimation are also in a varying degree capable of resisting actual deviations from these assumptions. It is in view of such circumstances that (WDD)'s models of budget requests and appropriations should be examined more closely. The key hypotheses in (WDD)'s analysis are that the relations of budget requests and the relations of budget appropriations are constant periodically, i.e. that the structural parameters ay and p\j are constant during a given period, after which a discrete change takes place, which is followed by the stability of one more period, etc. This assumption, that the structural parameters are time-vary ing, changes the specification of the models; of e.g. model (1.1) the following holds good:


DIVL1845

(1.7)

i.e. also the structural parameters are given a time indexing. This generalization

Side 134

in the speciflcation of the models is in itself a step in the right direction. On the other hånd, the way in which (WDD) test their hypothesis of step-by-step stability with a few discrete structural jumps is of doubtful value. By (WDD) the result of the empirical testing is regarded as satisfactory and this empirical testing is in reality the only empirical support there is of the incrementalist decision theory of public resource allocation, in particular budgeting. If the results of the testing of (WDD)'s equations can be called in question, this has definite consequences for the test of incrementalism.

The purpose of the present paper is to evaluate the principles of incrementalism, (i) - (iii) above, by applying the budgetary behavior relations (1.1-6), in a structural analysis of some Swedish public budgetary processes. Such an evaluation requires a general framework for this structural analysis, i.e. we will allow for potential structural instabilities. Our first task is then, of course, to test whether structural variability is or is not the most plausible characteristic of the Swedish budgetary processes to be analyzed. After a short description of structures and data actually used we will therefore in section 2 give a review of approaches possible to follow in order to judge statistically the extent of structural variability. In this special analysis we will select two test techniques, and a thorough description of these as well as the testing results obtained are then given. The pervading conclusion will be the rejection of all stability hypotheses. When estimating the structural budgetary relations we then have to choose a technique especially adapted to structurally varying systems. Such estimation techniques will often be recursive, and we are here applying a general recursive estimation technique, viz. Kalman filtering. Kalman filtering is introduced in section 3, where we also give the estimation results thus obtained, indicating the extent and time for structural variability. Finally, section 4 gives some conclusive comments on this evaluation of incrementalism within the framework of Swedish budgetary structures.

2. Analysis of Two Swedish Budgetary Structures

2.1 Structures and data

For the purpose of examining (WDD)'s models of budgetary behavior, the relations of budget requests and the relations of appropriations respectively, we have statistically tested hypotheses of structural stability against hypotheses of structural variability, and for structural estimation

Side 135

applied an approach designed to handle structurally varying systems. The interest is focused on a structural analysis in the model (1.7) and in structurally time-varying versions of (1.4) and (1.6). Data from the sphere of activity of the National Swedish Board of Universities and Colleges and of the National Swedish Board of Education have been used for the time 1946-1979. In order to arrive at comparability between data for different periods, data have been aggregated due to organizational changes.

2.2 Testing for structural variability

Econometric models are essential parts of the economic structural analysis. Generally, econometric modeling presupposes an assumption of structural stability, i.e. that the structural parameters are constant over time. Sometimes, this rather restrictive definition of the concept "structural stability" is relaxed by allowing for random variations (transitory variations) but rejecting permanent changes. When talking about structural variability it is convenient to distinguish between two sets of cases. In the first type, structural changes occur at a limited number of points in time, but the structure is stable between these points. In the second set of cases, the structural variability is assumed to be described by stochastic processes. The interest here is focused on problems connected with structural variability according to the second type.

Graphical representation of recursive estimates is generally not sufficient when testing stability against various alternatives of structural variability. Consequently, there is a strong need for stability significance tests. Such tests are partly based on recursive cumulated residuals, partly on various assumptions of parameter variation. Some tests are approximate, some are exact. Various inferential approaches, e.g. maximum likelihood, maximum invariance, etc., are used. However, all tests developed so far are designed for unirelational, multiple or simple, linear regression models.

Most stability tests will concern the linear regression model


DIVL1874

(2.1)

where xt is a p-dimensional row vector of regressors, (3t is a parameter
vector, and et is a stochastic scalar, where


DIVL1880
Side 136

If e = (£,,... ,Bt)' , we have


DIVL1884

For some tests we especially consider the simple regression model where
p= 1.

As the present state of the art does not allow us to formulate explicit alternative hypotheses concerning structural variability, as a specific alternative to the characteristics of incrementalism, we will here restrict ourselves to the application of tests adapted for just general non-stability.

Recursive residuals will be of fundamental importance here. In order to
define these, we introduce


DIVL1892

and


DIVL1896

DIVL1898

If the parameters p\ in (2.1) are stable over time, the least-squares
estimate based on t observations will be


DIVL1902

with covariance as


DIVL1906

The recursive residuals are then defined as


DIVL1910

(2.2)

If the hypothesis of structural stability is true


DIVL1916

and wt is a serially independent process.

Side 137

The CUSUM test (see e.g. Brown et al., 1975) is based on the cumulative
sums


DIVL1922

(2.3)

where


DIVL1928

Under the structural stability hypothesis, i.e. if 8i = ... =6t=6


DIVL1932

The stability hypothesis is rejected, if


DIVL1936

for any t in [p + 1, T], and where c is a constant, the value of which
determines the confidence level of the test:

c = 1.143 corresponds to .01 confidence level,
c = .948 corresponds to .05 confidence level.

The constants c are, however, only approximate.

An alternative to the CUSUM test is obtained if oe in (2.3) is estimated
by


DIVL1946

(2.4)

where co = Ewt/(T - p). Estimation of oe by (2.4) does not change the distribution of Wn, given the structural stability hypothesis. However, this modification is shown to increase power properties of the CUSUM test. See e.g. Garbade (1977) and Harvey and Phillips (1976) for robustness evaluations.

If Wn is replaced by W2t, where


DIVL1954

(2.5)

Side 138

the CUSUMQ test is obtained. Obviously, W2t is a monotonically increa
sing process with maximum W2T = 1. From (2.5) it is found that


DIVL1960
Side 139

and then it may be shown that 1 - W2t has a beta distribution with parameters a* =-1 + (T~p)/2, and (3* =-1 + (t - p)/2, i.e. the mean value of W2t is (t - p)/(T - p). For the stability testing procedure the following confidence interval for W2t is to be used:


DIVL1973

Figure 2. Testing for structural stability in the relation (1.4): appropriations as a function of requests. The research councils.

Side 140

DIVL1964

where c* is determined subject to the desired significance level (see e.g.
Durbin, 1969). Thus, the structural stability hypothesis is rejected, if


DIVL1968

2.3 Empirical test results

The CUSUM test, the alternative CUSUM test where at is determined according to (2.4), and the CUSUMQ test have been applied in order to examine whether structural relations for budget requests and for appropriations formalized in (1.1-6) are structurally stable. From these tests it follows that we cannot reject stability hypotheses by CUSUM (and its variant), but that we will always reject the stability hypotheses by CUSUMQ. This difference in test conclusions depends mainly on differences in test power properties between CUSUM and CUSUMQ. The CUSUMQ test is generally characterized by clearly better power properties, i.e. the possibility to reject a false stability hypothesis is higher if using CUSUMQ instead of CUSUM tests. Consequently, we feel greater confidence in the testing procedures based on CUSUMQ and we will therefore reject the stability hypotheses. The results obtained with the CUSUMQ tests are illustrated in Figures 1-2. The dotted lines in Figures 1 and 2 describe the observed values of the CUSUMQ test statistic W2t in (2.5). If the structural relations (1.4) and (1.6), respectively, in fact are structurally stable, the values of W2t are expected to follow the diagonal curves, determined as (t-p)/(T-p). The two sets of parallel diagonal lines describe the limits for non-rejection of the stability hypothesis for various test significance levels. Subject to a correct structural stability hypothesis these significance levels indicate the probability that the observed W2t still will cross these limits. As is seen in Figures 1 and 2, both test situations illustrated here clearly indicate rejection of the stability hypothesis. It should be observed that these test charts can not be directly used to verify the time and extent of structural variability. Such information is better reached by the structural estimates given below.

3. Kalman Filtering for Structural Analysis

3.1 The Kalman filter

If the behavior models for the processes of budget requests and appropnations

Side 141

DIVL2037

Figure 3. Structural parameters in the equation: appropriations as a function of last year's appropriations. The National Swedish Board of Universities and Colleges 1949-1979 (aggregation of bureaus).

are characterized by some type of structural instability, it may be difficult or impossible to quantify this variation of structure in a reliable way by means of ordinary least-square estimation, which (WDD) do. (WDD) estimate the models of budget requests and appropriations with a statistical inference approach which is not particularly adapted to models with time-varying parameters. The incremental model for budgetary behavior based on (WDD)'s model analyses should be subjected to renewed examination on the basis of better methods of model estimation, before this theory can be assumed to be valid for the decision mechanism in public resource allocation. In structural analysis of data it is essential to use appropriate methods of estimation of parameters. In recent years the so-called Kalman filter method has been generally proposed as a suitable method for estimation of parameters in structurally time-varying models. The applicability of the method to the estimation of structurally time-varying

Side 142

DIVL2040

Figure 4. Structural parameters in the equation: appropriations as a function of last year's appropriations. State higher education 1950-1979.

social science models has been tested inter alia in Brånnås and Westlund (1980). The results of this testing are very promising. With Kaiman filtering we make a structural analysis of data on the activities of two government agencies on the basis of (WDD)'s models for budget requests behavior and appropriations behavior. At the same time (WDD)'s approach to the estimation of parameters is applied with a view to making a comparative analysis of how the results of the two methods

Side 143

differ and what consequences these differences have for the testing of incrementalism. First, however, a brief presentation of the Kalman filter method for the purpose of giving a picture of the fundamental function of the method.

Suppose that the structural model consists of a linear behavior relation:


DIVL1995

(3.1)

where yt is a dependent variable, xt = (xit, X2t,...., xPt) denotes a sequence
of p independent variables, (in the equation (1.1) is p = 1, in (1.2) p = 2,
etc), a't = (ait, (X2t, ..., aPt) is a vector with the p respective structural
parameters, and £t denotes a random remainder. The remainder et is
supposed to be normally distributed with the anticipated value Eet = 0


DIVL2043

Figure 5. Structural parameters in the equation: appropriations as a function of requests. The research councils 1950-1979.

Side 144

and constant, finite variance, Var et = oh The structural parameters are thus assumed to vary with the time. A relatively general assumption concerning this variability in time can be summed up in a simplified way in the following parameter model:


DIVL2001

(3.2)

The model (3.2) thus represents a system of p relations, where every parameter cti, t + i is supposed to vary stochastically (vt), and through some systematic change dependent on an earlier actual parameter value (Ftat). The so-called transition matrix Ft of the order (p x p) is often supposed to be time-invariant (i.e. Ft = F for all t), and often identical with or approximatively equal to the identity matrix. The remainder vector vt is normally assumed to be p-dimensionally normally distributed, with expected values Evt = 0 (zero vector), and with variance - covariance matrix Q. If the p stochastical error terms in (3.2) are assumed to be independent, the matrix Q is diagonal, where the diagonal elements correspond to the variances for vu (i = 1,2, ..., p). Finally et and every element in the vector vt are supposed to be independent. Models (3.1) and (3.2) form together the starting-point for application of the Kalman filter for structural analysis and the following estimating equation is obtained.


DIVL2046

Figure 6. Structural parameters in the equation: requests as a function of last year's appropriations. The Swedish Board of Education 1946-1979.

Side 145

DIVL2007

(3.3)

where

at + l/t = Ft at/t

(3.4)

By ak/i is meant Kalman estimation of ak at the time k based on information up to and including time 1. The term (yt + i - x't + iat+ i/t) therefore corresponds to an actual error in forecasting at the time t + 1, i.e. every new estimation cu+i/t+i is given recursively by a process of weighting together the preceding estimation at/t and the present error in forecasting. The process of weighting together depends onGt + i, (the so-called filter gain) which is arrived at according to:


DIVL2019

(3.5)

The size of the elements in Gt + i decreases if öf increases, i.e. increased uncertainty in model (3.1) leads to diminished credit in new data and therefore to a more conservative updating by means of (3.3). If on the other hand the elements in Q increase, also Gt + i, increases (see 3.7) below), i.e. observed variations in data affect the recursive parameter estimation more strongly. Zt + i/t + i in (3.5) corresponds to the estimated variance - covariance matrix for at + i/t + i, and is calculated recursively according to


DIVL2025

(3.6)

where


DIVL2031

(3.7)

Thus, the Kalman filter method has a recursive structure, which renders it attractive for practical application. Given the basic assumptions described above it is further characterized by good theoretical properties. However, when the method is applied, certain a priori specifications are required initially, namely (i) oi, (ii) Q, (iii) F.t, and (iv) ao /o. Of course, the theoretical properties of the method are influenced by the possibility of specifying these entities satisfactorily. There is, however, a manifest robustness vis-å-vis the specification of the variance elements o^and Q.

Side 146

On the other hånd the transitions in Ft and the initial parameters ao /o should be specified with greater care. In most cases it is here appropriate to estimate these preliminary entities quantitatively on the basis of the data at hånd concerning the process studies.

3.2 Some results

The results of the comparative analysis between the method used by (WDD) and the Kalman filter method are summed up in Figures 3-6. In every figure the broken curve illustrates the result of parameter estimation on application of Kalman filtering. In the figures are also given the results arrived at on application of conventional regression analysis, for the whole period as well as for parts of it. The figures show that the results of the regression analysis to some extent catch the structural variability that is estimated via Kalman filter. For the regression analyses in Figures 4 and 6 the results of the estimation seem unreliable. This is not surprising because inferior precision and deficient correctness of anticipated values in the regression analysis are to be expected, if the specified regression model is actually characterized by structural variability. The Kalman filtering adapted to such situations therefore appears as considerably more reliable. Furthermore, as a rule more information about structural variability is given on estimation with Kalman filter. This appears very clearly in Figures 3-6. In order to initiate the recursive Kalman filtering necessary, a priori specifications have been initiated by means of results obtained on regression analysis of the whole period of time. Of course, here is the cause of some uncertainty in the Kalman filtering. However, as has been stated earlier, the specifications of variance should hardly play any significant role. With regard to the initial parameter values several alternatives have normally been tested. Throughout we have then found great robustness vis-å-vis these a priori specifications, too. Already after a few points of time the alternative estimated parameter processes have connected on to each other (see e.g. Figures 4 and 5). Therefore we are of the opinion that potential uncertainty in the Kalman estimation in the first place can be associated with uncertainty in the initial transition assumptions that are made (see (3.2)). We intend later on to analyze the question of robustness which is closely connected with the problem of trying to find alternative decision rules that are valid for the description of decisions on appropriations and budget requests.

The question if the incremental decision theory is correct for budgetary
decisions may vis-å-vis the data summed up in Figures 3-6 be specified
into: to what degree do the data support that budget decisions satisfy the

Side 147

three key principles in Wildavsky's budget theory: the principle of marginalism,
the principle of an equitable share, and the principle of the
existence of a base.

(1) Marginalism: this principle says that decisions on budget requests and on appropriations involve a minor change in relation to the appropriations of the previous year and the budget requests of the previous year or of the same year. Data by no means confirm that this principle should be valid generally. On the contrary, both Figures 3 and 5 show changes that can hardly be interpreted as inconsiderable. The fact that budget decisions sometimes satisfy the principle of marginalism is no support for the principle being valid generally. Such a generalization involves disregard of the occurrence of a different decision principle not involving marginalism, and failure to clarify when the principle of marginalism applies and when it does not apply.

(2) Equitable share: this principle says that decisions on appropriations and on budget requests tend to show a constant change over an interval of time. There are intervals of time when data can be said to satisfy this property, but what is most salient in Figures 3 and 6 is that data indicate that an entirely different decision principle is applied. Nor can Figures 4 and 5 be taken as unambiguous support for the principle of an equitable share. It is obvious that this principle is sometimes satisfied by data, e.g. during the 1950's in Figure 3 and during the 1960's in Figure 5, but a generalization involves disregard of the fact that data indicate that other decision principles are applied during certain invervals of time.

(3) Existence of a base: this principle says that decisions on budget requests and on appropriations revolve around a base that is fixed over an interval of time. Can this base be identified in the data in the figures? It is evidently difficult, not to say impossible, to identify a base in Figure 3 for the time 1960-1979. The same applies to Figure 5 for the time from the late fifties onward. Figure 4 indicates that a base can be identified, but that it varies at different levels for different intervals of time, whereas Figure 6 indicates that submitters of budget requests have different ideas of what a base should be like at different times. Again: the principle misleads more than it enlightens. During certain intervals of time decisions on appropriations and on budget requests appear to revolve around a base; during other intervals of time no base is identifiable. It must be essential to clarify when this principle is applied and when some other principle is used.

Side 148

4. Conclusions

When we subject the widely accepted decision theory within organizational theory and policy analysis, the so-called incrementalism, to an empirical examination through an analysis of a number of well-known budgetary models by Wildavsky and collaborators, we get a negative result: falsification. If data are described with a regression model which permits that the structural variability that characterizes data does not disappear in the model but is reproduced in the parameter estimation (via the so-called Kalman filter method), it can be shown that incrementalism does not agree with data. The three key principles of the incrementalist theory are too crude for the understanding of budget decisions. It should be strongly emphasized that the falsification of incrementalism has been made with incremental models on a set of data which, if these had been described with a conventional method for parameter estimation, would have confirmed incrementalism. Thus, it cannot be asserted that the incremental models suit US, but not Swedish, budget data.

In some innovative articles Wildavsky and Dempster have outlined an
approach to the study of budget-making which explicitly recognizes the
importance of structural changes. They write:

'Our hope in this paper is to give new meaning to the concept of incrementalism applied to budgetary processes. This new meaning is central to our previous work and can be operationally linked to it in precise terms. By identifying 'incremental' with the regular relationship between Congress and bureaux, as expressed in our equations, non-incremental becomes equivalent to a shift in these relations.' (Wildavsky & Dempster, p. 371)

We believe that it is necessary to take one further step: to seriously question the basic hypothesis in all incrementalist theory, the assumption about structural regularity or stability. We have exposed this hypothesis to a refined statistical test and the data do not corroborate the hypothesis. Our next step will be the attempt to construct a theory of budgetary decision-making which does not contain the Juggernaut of incrementalism, the assumption of structural stability. Of course, any extension of a theory of decision principles explaining budgetary behavior into the field of resource mobilization accounting for decisions on taxation and charges would constitute a significant improvement of the present state of knowledge.

REFERENCES

Anton, T. J. 1966. The Politics of State Expenditure in Illinois. Urbana: University of Illinois
Press.

Braybrooke, D. and C. Lindblom. 1963. A Strategy of Decision. New York: Free Press.

Brown, R. L., Durbin, J. and Evans J. M. 1975. Techniques for testing the constancy of
regression relationships over time. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series B, 37,
149-192.

Brännas, K. and Westlund, A. 1980. On the recursive estimation of stochastic and time-varying
parameters in econometric systems, Optimization Techniques (ed. Iracki et al.).
Berlin: Springer Verlag.

Dempster, M.A.H. & Wildawsky, A. 1979. On change: Or, there is no magic size for an
increment. Political Studies 27, 371-389.

Durbin, J. 1969. Tests for serial correlation in regression analysis based on the peridogram of
least square residuals. Biometrika 56, 1-15.

Garbade, K. 1977. Two methods for examining the stability of regression coefficients.
Journal of the American Statistical Association 72, 54-63.

Harvey, A. C. and Phillips, G. D. A. 1976. Testing for stochastic parameters in regression
models. Paper at the Econometric Society Meeting, Helsinki.

Heclo, H. & Wildavsky, A. 1974. The Private Government of Public Money. London:
Macmillan.

Lindblom, C. 1965. The Intelligence of Democracy. New York: Free Press.

Wildavsky, A., Davis, O. A. & Dempster, M. A. H. 1971. A Theory of the Budgetary
Process. In Wildavsky, A., The Revolt against the Masses and Other Essays on Politics
and Public Policy. New York: Basic Books.