Scandinavian Political Studies, Bind 1 (New Series) (1978) 1

Proportional Representation in Scandinavia: Irnplications for Finland

Markku Laakso, University of Helsinki

Rein Taagepera, University of California

Side 43

Resumé

The comparative study of electoral system requires uniform methods easily
applicable to every country's electoral data. In this paper we have presented two
such possibilities: a new graphical method that portrays the proportionality profile
of a country's electoral rule, and measures to calculate the systematic and
random deviation from proportionality. The empirical data consist of election
results from Denmark, Finland, Norway, and Sweden. Around 1950, Denmark,
Norway, and Sweden changed from the d'Hondt method of allocation to the
modified Sainte Lague rule. The consequences of this shift represent the primary
focus of this article. What can the present Finnish constitutional reformers learn
from the Scandinavian experience? According to the empirical results, three
distinct patterns of proportionality profiles can be distinguished: 1) systems
involving nationwide adjustment seats, 2) modified St. Lague (without adjustment
seats) and 3) d'Hondt (without adjustment seats). The d'Hondt system gives a
high advantage ratio to large parties, the modified Sainte Lague method favors
middle-size parties, and the adjustment seats system overrides the basic characteristics
of both the d'Hondt and modified Sainte Lague methods. The proportionality
indices show the modified Sainte Lague to be more proportional than the
d'Hondt method. The proportionality of elections is nearly perfect with adjustment
seats system irrespective of the method of allocation applied.

1. Introduction

The objectives of this paper are: to apply a new graphical method to elections for the second (or single) legislative chamber, to evaluate the performance of Scandinavian electoral systems, and to contribute to the current re-evaluation of the Finnish system.

Political scientists have for a long time confronted the problems raised by electoral systems. How does the electoral system relate to the party system? What are the political consequences of electoral laws? According to Duverger (1954, 239)

Side 44

'. . .the simple-majority single ballot system encourages the two-party
system; on the contrary both the simple-majority system with second
ballot and proportional representation favour multipartism.'

But many scholars have shown that the relationship is not so simple, especially in the most famous empirical study by Douglas W. Rae (1967) in which he analyzes election results from twenty western democracies. However, Rae's analysis is based for the most part on a comparison of majority and proportional systems. The question of differences within the 'family' of proportional systems is not considered. What happens if a country changes one proportional electoral rule for another? If a country wishes to reduce the number of parties to ensure a more effective functioning of its decision-making system, can this goal be reached by another electoral rule?

The Scandinavian experience offers a highly interesting research area in this respect. Around 1950, Denmark, Norway and Sweden changed from the d'Hondt method of allocation to the modified Sainte Lague rule. The consequences of this shift represent the primary focus of this article. The results are especially important when we keep in mind the present discussion in Finland on constitutional reform, which also includes a. re-evaluation of the electoral system. What can Finland learn from the Scandinavian experience?

Representative democracy has many common features in all Nordic countries. All five countries apply the list system of proportional representation in multi-member constituencies. However, there are certain important differences in transforming votes into parliamentary seats. Denmark, Norway, and Sweden apply the odd-number Sainte Lagué rule modified through the stipulation of a 1.4 barrier against party fragmentation (divisors 1.4, 3, 5, and so on). Denmark and Sweden further reserve a certain number of seats in a national pool to be used as so-called adjustment seats. Finland and Iceland use the d'Hondt system under which the total number of votes cast for each party list is divided in turn by 1, 2, 3,

. . „ etc. The well-known fact that the d' Hondt system favours the larger parties has given rise in Finland to pressures to change the electoral rule to the more proportional system adopted in the other Scandinavian countries.

Empirical studies of some Nordic voting data, using different electoral rules, lead to the same conclusions: the d'Hondt method systematically favors larger parties, and if proportional representation is the ideal, then the modified St. Lagué system seems to be preferable on theoretical

Side 45

grounds (see Rokkan and Hjellum, 1966: 237-246; Laakso and Taagepera, 1977, Loosemore and Hanby, 1971: 467-477). However, there are secondary features which have a marked effect on the functioning of the basic rule: an ability to form electoral alliances attenuates the disproportionality inherent in d'Hondt, while nationwide adjustment seats may abolish it altogether. On the other hand, a threshold clause makes even the St. Lagué system more disproportional. The size of electoral districts can play a major role, if there are no adjustment seats: a proportional representation system (be it d'Hondt or St. Lagué) approaches a simple plurality system when there are very few seats per district.

The effect of party size (in terms of its share of votes) has been mostly discussed in the form of a dichotomy: are large or small parties favored by a given electoral system? But one could conceive of a system that favors middle-size parties at the expense of both extremes. We need a way to represent empirically the effect of party size without any theoretical preconceptions.

We will first present 'proportionality profiles' of Scandinavian electoral systems under the d'Hondt and St. Lagué rules, and try to characterize the resulting differences. In the second part, systematic and random deviation from proportionality is defined and calculated for the four Scandinavian countries. For Denmark the time period of elections is 1932-1973: eight elections when d'Hondt was applied and similarly eight elections under Sainte Lagué. For Finland we have chosen two periods before and after World War II (1919-1939, and 1945-1972) to see if there are changes over time when the same electoral system is applied for a long period. For Norway the elections extend over the periods 1930-1949 (5 elections, d'Hondt with electoral alliances allowed) and 1953-1973 (6 elections, the modified Sainte Lagué rule). Finally, for Sweden the time periods chosen are 1921 to 1948 (8 elections, d'Hondt) and 1952 to 1973 (6 elections with the modified Sainte Lagué rule, 2 elections with a 4% vote threshold and modified Sainte Lagué).

2. Proportionality Profiles

Our procedure is the following:

1) For each party, calculate the ratio Ai=Si/vi of its share of seats (si) and
its share of votes (vi),

2) Plot this 'advantage ratio' versus the share of votes (vi)

The advantage ratio Ai shows how much a party is favored/disadvantaged
by the electoral rule. If Ai>l, the seat share of a party is greater than its

Side 46

DIVL628

vote share: if Ai<l, the reverse conclusion holds. Note that perfect proportionality requires the equality of si and Vi, so that Ai= 1. Our advantage ratio is analogous to Dahl's 'index of advantage' (Dahl, 1956:114). If we plot Ai vs. v; we can see how the ratio depends on the size of a party's share of the vote. If the correlation is positive the electoral rule favors large parties: a negative correlation leads to the opposite conclusion.

In Figure 1 the plot Ai vs. v; is presented for four Scandinavian countries.
Most of the d'Hondt systems show a common pattern of high advantage

Side 47

DIVL630

ratio for large parties and a gradually decreasing one for smaller parties (Figures la, b, c, and e). The general trend curve has been sketched into these plots without aiming at a best least-square fit (note that before carrying out such a least-square fit we would have to decide on the general shape of the curve to be fitted, a decision of a theoretical nature that we prefer to avoid at the present stage). We tentatively conclude that this is the typical proportionality profile for pure d'Hondt systems. The breakeven point (where Ai= 1) tends to occur for vote shares ranging from 12 to

Side 48

DIVL632

18%. Agrarian center parties tend to have an unusually high advantage for a given vi (Figures la and e), reflecting a favorable geographical distribution of their votes. The advantage ratio of large parties tends to level off at Ai= 1.10 to 1.15. Systems with large dominating parties (Figures la, c, and e) seem to have the same profile as the Finnish one where no parties have more than 30% of the vote (Figure lb). Very small parties tend to have an advantage ratio close to zero.

In contrast to all other d'Hondt systems, Denmark, which uses nationwide

Side 49

DIVL634

adjustment seats, presents a completely different profile. The advantage ratio seems to be close to unity irrespective of party size, except that the scatter of individual Ai values increases for small Vi. We tentatively conclude that adjustment seats override the basic d'Hondt characteristics to such an extent that it may be misleading to describe it as a d'Hondt system as far as the political results of electoral rules are concerned.

The two modified St. Lagué systems with no adjustment seats (Figures

Side 50

DIVL636

Id and f) also offer a common pattern that may be typical of St. Lagué: the advantage of large parties is abolished (as intended by St. Lagué), and the modification with 1.4 as the first divisor prevents the opposite advantage to small parties (see Rokkan, 1968:14). In fact, very small parties again have near-zero Ai. The outcome is a moderate (Ai around 1.05) but fairly clear advantage for medium-size parties (those with 7 to 15% of the vote). Part of the peak is due to the aforementioned geographical advantage that agrarian parties tend to have, but other medium-size parties also tend to do

Side 51

DIVL638

relatively well under the modified St. Lagué rule.

The Danish case of modified St. Lagué with adjustment seats (Figure lh) has a profile quite different from other St. Lagué systems. In fact, this profile is very similar to that of the earlier d'Hondt system with adjustment seats (Figure lg): Ai=l, except for extremely low v; where Ai is close to zero for all systems considered.

The discussion of electoral systems in the Nordic countries has mainly
operated with two formulae: d'Hondt and modified St. Lagué. Our proportionality

Side 52

DIVL640

profiles suggest that, as far as effect on proportionality is
concerned, we should distinguish between three distinct patterns:

1. Systems involving nationwide adjustment seats.

2. Modified St. Lagué (without adjustment seats).

3. d'Hondt (without adjustment seats).

A fourth variant may have been introduced in 1969 by the Swedish combination

Side 53

DIVL642

of adjustment seats with a vote threshold, but data are still limited.
The likely profile is Ai= 1 (similar to other adjustment seat systems), with a
sudden drop to Ai=o at the threshold.

The post -1969 Swedish electoral system seems to involve a needlessly
complex maze of unintended 'checks and balances': the large later divisors
(3,5,7,. . .) of St. Lagué, originally intended to keep down the large
party advantage, are superfluous since adjustment seats ensure an even
advantage at any party size over the vote threshold. The modified first

Side 54

divisor (1.4), originally intended to keep down small party advantage, is superfluous since the threshold takes drastic care of these small parties. The somewhat simpler d'Hondt system would achieve exactly the same result, if employed in conjunction with adjustment seats and a vote threshold.

The lesson for Finland seems to be that the quest for proportionality would be best served by the introduction of nationwide adjustment seats. The choice between d'Hondt and St. Lagué is unimportant when adjustment seats are used, as shown by the Danish experience. But this choice may be unimportant even without adjustment seats, for the following local reasons: present-day Finland lacks parties in the 7 to 15% vote range, which could profit from a switch to St. Lagué, and it also lacks large parties (over 30% of the vote) which would clearly profit from the d'Hondt system. It seems from our profiles that Finland is not likely to gain anything from a switch from d'Hondt to St. Lagué (except a feeling of being part of the Nordic crowd); nor would it lose anything (except for the costs of a changeover to more complex calculations). The real issue is whether to complement the existing d'Hondt framework with adjustment seats and/or a vote threshold (either through an explicit threshold or through reduced district size).

3. Systematic and Random Deviation from Proportionality, and Effective Number of Parties

We have presented in detail the measures of the random and systematic deviation from proportionality in a separate article (Laakso and Taagepera, 1977). Because the measurement is the same here we need refer only briefly to analytic methods involved.

Usually the deviation from proportionality is defined as follows
(Loosemore and Hanby, 1971).


DIVL653

(1)

where n == the number of parties in elections
si = the seat share of the i-th party,
v; = the vote share of the i-th party

Perfect proportionality is only reached (Di = 0) when for all i the seat
share is equal to the vote share. If a party with zero votes won all the seats,
then Di would reach its maximum of 1.

Side 55

Starting from the assumptions originally presented by Henri Theil the
seat share of the i-th party should rationally be close to the value given by
the formula (Theil 1969: 521-525)


DIVL663

(2)

The larger the value of a, the more large parties are systematically favored. With a = 1 perfect proportionality is obtained and with a= 3 we have the famous 'cube law' which discriminates heavily against non-local small parties. The formula (2) describes a systematic distribution of seats.

Random deviation can now be expressed, in an analogy to Equation (1),
by i ,


DIVL671

(3)

For a given set of votes (vi) and the seat distribution (si), Da can be calculated for any value of el The task is to find the 'optimal' value for a (denoted by aoPt) so that Da is minimized. The residual deviation is designated as Dmin which represents the random deviation from proportionality in the sense that it profits neither small nor large parties on the basis of their size.

Thus the systematic deviation is expressed by


DIVL679

(4)

where Di represents the total deviation from proportionality. Because Dsyst does not tell us whether large or small parties are favored, aoP t may be a better measure of systematic disproportionality. For aoPt>l we know that larger parties are favored, and if aoPt<l, smaller parties win an extra bonus from the electoral rule. Note that the small middle-size party bonus of the modified Sainte Lagué rule would be treated as random deviation in this context.

The effective number of parties is defined as


DIVL687

(5)

Side 56

DIVL707

Table I. Deviation from Proportionality and Effective Number of Parties in the Four Scandinavian Countries (Mean Values)*

where p; is the fractional share of votes or of seats for the i-th party. The summation is over all n parties which actually obtain seats or votes. The effective number of parties on the vote level (Nv) is usually larger than that on the seat level (Ns) (see Laakso and Taagepera, 1977 b).

Table I gives the mean deviation from proportionality and effective number of parties for the four Scandinavian countries. The values for Finland are adopted from Laakso and Taagepera (1977). The election years under d'Hondt and St. Lagué are the same as in Figure 1, except for Finland.

In Denmark elections under the d'Hondt rule with additional seats are very proportional (years 1932-1953). The aoP t value is quite near 1.00 and the total deviation Di is also small. Systematic deviation from proportionality (Dsyst) is minimal because of small values of aoP t. The very high proportionality of the d'Hondt rule in Denmark is explained by the use of the additional adjustment seats. The adoption of the modified St. Lagué rule paradoxically made elections more disproportional, although aoP t is still quite low. After the change in the electoral rule the Dsyst value also grew.

The results from Finland based on the same election results but on
different hypothetical electoral rules show that, if Finland had applied the

Side 57

DIVL710

Table 11. The Proportion of Systematic Deviation from Total Deviation

Sainte Lagué rule, elections would have been much more proportional but the number of effective parties on the parliamentary seat level would have grown markedly (Laakso and Taagepera, 1977). In Denmark the average value of the effective number of parties has increased on both the seat (Ns) and vote (Nv) levels. Whether this tendency is due to the change of the electoral rule is doubtful.

In Norway the results agree with those calculated for Finland. Adoption of the modified Sainte Lagué rule has made elections more proportional. This can be seen from the decrease in the aoP t values and in the difference (Nv-Ns). Although there is a slight decrease on the vote level (Nv), the number of effective parties in Norway has remained constant at the seat level (Ns) because the modified Sainte Lagué rule is more proportional than d'Hondt. It should be noted that the mean value of aoP t under the d'Hondt method (1.20) is slightly larger in Norway than in Finland (1.12 with electoral alliances permitted). If Finland had applied the modified St. Lagué, its aoP t would have been 1.07 compared to Norway's 1.11.

In Sweden the d'Hondt rule has been markedly more disproportional than the St. Lagué method. The mean aoP t value for d'Hondt is 1.12 (as in Finland) while for the modified St. Lagué in elections 1952-1968 it was 1.06. Thereafter the system of additional nationwide seats has further reduced the deviation from perfect proportionality, and if we also take these elections into account the mean value for aoP t since 1952 is 1.05. These results closely resemble the theoretical calculations for Finland. In Sweden the effective number of parties has decreased under the modified St. Lagué rule on the seat level (Ns), though remaining the same at the vote level (Nv). In this respect the results are analogous to Norway.

It is informative for a comparison of different Scandinavian countries on the basis of their electoral rales to determine how systematic the deviation from proportionality has been. This can be calculated simply on the basis of Di and Dsyst values. The results are presented in Table 11.

Side 58

The results from Norway and Sweden resemble each other. In both countries the Dsyst values are approximately twice as great under d'Hondt as under the modified St. Lagué rule. In Finland the tendency is the same but the ratio Dsyst/Di is markedly smaller, presumably due to larger electoral districts. In Denmark the effect of supplementary seats overrides the d'Hondt - St. Lagué difference. In fact the modified St. Lagué method gives a more systematic deviation from perfect proportionality than does d'Hondt.

4. The Effect of Electoral Law on the Party System; the Lesson of Scandinavian Experiences for Finland

The problems of comparative research in the area of electoral systems are many, simply because no two countries apply exactly the same electoral system. The Scandinavian countries are quite similar in many respects but there are also many important differences which make general conclusions difficult.

The comparative study of electoral rules has shown the modified St. Lagué to be more proportional than the d'Hondt method. The exception of Denmark is explained by its additional seats system. However, the effect of electoral rules on the effective number of parties is not clear. The problems lies in the interpretation of changes in the Nv values. Does the electoral system affect the fragmentation of the party system on the voter level? The answer cannot be stated explicitly. The electoral rule may be one factor, but its importance is difficult to estimate because of a number of other factors that may have an effect on the dispersion/concentration tendencies in the multi-party system. But if the Ns values remain constant irrespective of the changes in the Nv values (as in Norway and Sweden), the results support the general conclusion presented by Laakso and Taagepera (1977) on the basis of Finnish election data. The problem of Nv was not faced in the study of Finnish elections because Nv was held constant when applying different election procedures to the same voting data.

It is difficult to predict what will happen when the electoral rule is changed. This dilemma is very real for the Finnish constitutional reformers. If we had to give them any recipes, we might offer those tentatively set out in Table 111. If they change the electoral rule from d'Hondt to the modified St. Lagué rule, as the Liberal and Swedish People's Party have proposed, then the proportionality of the elections will probably increase. But what are the consequences for the party system? Will it move towards

Side 59

DIVL728

Table 111. Tentative Suggestions on How to Reach Various Political Objectives through a Manipulation of Proportional Representation

further fragmentation as the results based on the constant Nv values indicate? Or will the development be the same as in Norway and Sweden where Nv remained quite constant after electoral reform? This problem was also noticed in a general form by Douglas W. Rae (1967: 145-146) when he wrote:

'. . . what can development analysis of elections in individual nations add to our understanding of the relationship between party system and electoral law? ... Is it not likely that a fairly general pattern of development - resting on a large set of variables, only one of which is electoral law -underlies the contemporary party systems we have been discussing?'

The comparative study of electoral systems is necessary in order to predict the political consequences of electoral reform. Such a comparative study needs uniform methods easily applicable to every country's electoral data. We have offered two such possibilities: methods that portray the proportionality profile of a country's electoral rule, and measures to calculate the systematic and random deviation from proportionality.

REFERENCES

Dahl, R. A. 1956. A Preface to Democratic Theory. Chicago: University Press.

Laakso, M. and Taagepera, R. 1977. 'Proportional Representation and Effective Number of
Parties in Finland', in press.

Laakso, M. and Taagepera, R. 1977 b. 'Effective Number of Parties: Theory, and Application
to West Europe', in press.

Loosemore, J. and Hanby, V. 1971. 'The Theoretical Limits of Maximal Distortion: Some
Analytic Expressions for Electoral Systems', British Journal of Political Science 1,
467-477.

Pesonen, P. 1972. 'Political Parties in the Finnish Eduskunta', in Patterson, S. C. and
Wahlke, J. C, eds., Comparative Legislative Behavior. New York: Wiley.

Rae, D. W. 1967. The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws. New Haven: Yale University
Press.

Rokkan, S. 1968. 'Elections: Electoral Systems', in International Encyclopedia of the Social
Sciences. New York: Collice-Macmillan.

Rokkan, S. and Hjellum, T. 1966. 'Norway: the Storting Election of September 1965',
Scandinavian Political Studies 1, 237-246.

Rokkan, S. and Meyriat, J. 1969! International Guide to Electoral Statistics. Vol. I: West
Europe. The Hague: Mouton.

Theil, H. 1969. 'The Desired Political Entropy', American Political Science Review 69,
521-525.