Scandinavian Political Studies, Bind 7 (1972)Models for Change in Voting BehaviorSØREN RISBJERG THOMSEN The Danish
Institute for Educational Research, Copenhagen 1. IntroductionThis article suggests one general and three specific models for the description of changes in the distribution of votes by political party for the geographic subareas within a given area. Data from Danish parliamentary elections from 1960 to 1968 are chosen to show how the models work. The main topics discussed are: What is uniform change? and What is differential change? Uniform change occurs when the support for a particular political party changes by the same amount in the same direction in all subareas, while differential change refers to deviation from uniform change in support for that party. In addition to
the description and testing of models for uniform and
differential Georg Rasch1 has
proposed a theory of measurement especially applicable
to 2. A Model for Uniform ChangeA tendency to uniform change, that is, approximately the same amount of change in all geographical subareas, has frequently been observed for parties in democratic countries. This tendency was observed in many Danish political districts 1960—1968, in four successive elections to the Danish parliament which have been analyzed by Borre and Stehouwer.2 The present
question is: How can we measure the amount of change in
the support A very common
method is to take the proportion received by the party,
of all Side 178
approach to construct a probability model, we take the proportion of votes for party h in subarea i in election t as an estimate of p£°, the probability that one voter chosen at random from the subarea has cast his vote for party h. That is, the stochastic equality (1) where a^ is the
number of people voting for party h, and Nit is the
number of From this
formula, there are several ways of formulating a model
for uniform Borre and Stehouwer3 compute the difference in the party's proportion of votes in two successive elections and use this difference as a measure of the amount of change. In probabilistic terms, the model for uniform change (between elections 1 and 2) is then (2) that is, the same
difference, 000,o00, is observed in all k subareas.
This model, however, fits badly with the actual Danish election statistics. Small parties, in particular, show systematic deviations from this model — for these parties the difference tends to be proportional to the proportion of votes in election 1. This suggests another model for uniform change: (3) that is, the same
ratio, cOO,c00, is observed in all subareas. This model has
been used by Tage Bild4 to analyze the (very small) vote
for the (4) That is, the model does not imply that the sum of the proportions received by all parties in one subarea in an election must equal one. With such a model one can get the following results: Suppose the votes for a party in one subarea increase from 10 percent to 20 percent of the total vote. Suppose that in another subarea the same party begins with 50 percent of all votes cast. Then, according to formula (3), in the second subarea this party's support must double to 100 percent Side 179
of the vote in
order to show uniform change, without regard to what
happens Therefore it seems more reasonable to use a model which describes the support for one party relative to the support for other parties. This support for each party will be described by a parameter X^ which is not known a priori for any of the parties. The model suggested is: (5) That is, the
probability of voting for party h is the parameter X^0
divided by the Furthermore, let
us define uniform change as the condition that (f\ That is, the same
ratio, c®*, is assumed to appear in all subareas for a
particular Formula (6) can
also be expressed by (7) where Xs° is
separated into two parameters, one independent of
elections, the other That this formula
implies (6) can be seen by the fact that (8) That is, the
ratio between two support parameters is the same for all
subareas. (9) This model is a
version of Rasch's general model of measurement.5 The
model If desired, the
model can be applied to only n out of all m parties. The
formula (10) Side 180
where p£° can be
estimated by the proportion voting for party h in
relation to the For
generalization below of the model, a purely formal
logarithmic transformation (11) Thus (10) can be
written (12) Statistical
methods for testing 1 his model and estimating its
parameters are described The only test shown here will be a preliminary graphic test of model (12) on data from the elections of 1960, 1964, 1966, and 1968 for 41 subareas within the municipality of Copenhagen. The analysis will be limited to those eight parties which participated in all four elections: A Social Democrats, B Radicals, C Conservatives, D Liberals, E Justice Party, F Socialist People's Party, K Communists, U Independent Party. Side 181
Following the procedure described in Appendix 1, Figure 1 plots, for each of the 41 subareas, the relative support each party received in 1960 (measured by l^c) — l^; see Appendix 1) against the mean of the party's relative support in all 4 elections (measured by l^h>) — l..(h-)). If model (12) for uniform change fits the data, then the points should deviate only at random from a straight line with slope 1 for each party. (For convenience the graphs in Figure 1 are referred to different origins.) The data in Figure 1 show a remarkably close fit with the model, with two minor exceptions: parties E and U show greater deviations from their respective lines than the other parties. But one would expect this statistically because parties E and U receive very few votes. More interesting are the systematic deviations for parties B and U, where the points indicate better fit with straight lines having slopes greater than 1. (These deviations suggest a rule for generalizing this model to a model for differential change — see section 3 below). 6[h) measures the
relative support for party hin subarea i independent of
time Values of a[h) are indicated in Figure 2 for each election. Note for example that the relative support for party A (Social Democrats) appears fairly constant, support for B (Radicals) increased throughout the period, and support for U (Independent Party) decreased throughout the period. 3. Models for Differential ChangeExamination of 6[h)-values (relative support in a particular subarea) reveals two groups of positively correlated parties: A, F, K (worker-supported parties) and B, C, D, U (non-worker-supported parties), each group correlating negatively with the other. This suggests the assumption: (13) Side 182
That is, the
Ø^-values of party h are proportional to a parameter,
ois for the subarea (14) This model (the distribution analysis model of Rasch) can be tested on each election separately by maximum-likelihood estimation procedure.7 A method for preliminary graphic testing of the model is given by Christiansen and Stene8 and is applied to the Copenhagen data for 1960 in Figure 3. For each party, the residue from equal support in each area, measured by r£° (see Appendix 2), is plotted against the sign-weighted mean residue from equal support (measured by r£}). Side 183
If the model fits
the data, the points for each party should only deviate
at random The data fit the
model quite well, but not as closely as in the previous
analysis. For the Copenhagen data it was found that 0j as estimated separately for each election is approximately constant throughout the period 1960—1968.9 Also it is related approximately linearly to a measure for over-representation of manual workers in each subarea. Therefore (see equation (13)), 9(h) is interpreted as 'the degree of manual-worker orientation of party h'. Figure 4 shows values of yf® as estimated separately for each election. Minor changes in 9(h) are observed over time, and this indicates that 9(h) is time-dependent. As expected, the parties traditionally in favor of more equal income (A, F, K) have positive values of 9(h), while the more conservative parties (U, C, D) have negative values of 9(h). Party E (Justice Party) is in be ween, and it appears that B (Radicals) is approaching zero at the end of the period investigated. When, as in this
example, 9(h) is dependent on time, formula (14) must be
generalized 05) This differential
change is described by 9^, the orientation of party h at
election The model can be
further generalized into a model for differential change
with (16) Side 184
In this formula
0^ (BU, Øi2 „.., Øir) arid O?°: (cpj?, <få\ ...,
<$>) are vectors of d?) As in factor
analysis, tests of this model are not very conclusive
when the number A test can be
made, however, in the special case where only one of the
elements (18) that is, only the
first term is dependent on time. When this expression is
inserted (19) If this model for
differential change is compared with the model for
uniform This model fits the Copenhagen data quite well. (A simple preliminary test follows the procedure of Appendix 2, in computing the residues from the model in equation (12)). The model also fits the regional distribution of data from the same elections, previously published by Stehouwer and Borre in Scandinavian Political Studies.w For use with these data, the analysis includes eight political parties, plus the 'party' of non-voters. The close fit of the model with these data can be illustrated by the small differences between the actual and the 'computed' proportions (computed on the basis of estimated parameters) voting for each party in each subarea (region) in each election. The differences are in no instance greater than 2 percent, and are greater than 1 percent in only 17 out of 396 instances.11 Side 185
Table I shows that the differential change dimension oq is strongly positively correlated with degree of urbanization. Therefore (see formula (19)), we will call $® 'the degree of urban orientation of party h at election t'. Figure 5 shows values of p[h) for each election. Party B
(Radicals) shows a marked increase in urban orientation,
and there is 4. A Macro-Sociological Theory for Voting BehaviorIt has surprised me that most of the electoral data I have worked with so far can be described with such simple models. It is characteristic of the models that they describe the distribution of votes in geographic populations, with parameters either independent of time (independent of elections) or independent of space (independent of subareas within the total area). This simplicity of description indicates that voting populations in these subareas are useful macro-sociological entities for description of behavioral distributions. Furthermore, it indicates that these distributions can be explained by subarea characteristics which do not change over time and by characteristics of the election which are the same for all subareas in the total area. At this point we
introduce three assumptions consistent with the models
developed Assumption L
The more the image of a political party satisfies the
goals of the population The weakness of
assumption 1 is that there is no external definition of
what is Assumption 2.
The image of one political party at a particular
election is the same Side 186
I expect this assumption to hold only in very cohesive political regions where each subarea receives approximately the same political stimuli. It would not hold, for example, in situations where local political events are important (e.g. local municipal elections). Assumption 3.
The goals of the population in one subarea do not change
from one That is, the population in the subarea will be considered a macro-sociological entity with a certain distribution of individual goals. I expect this distribution to be dependent on basic socioeconomic factors that only change slowly, so that it can be regarded as constant over short periods of time. This assumption will be unrealistic during situations of violent political crisis or great socioeconomic change. Note that
assumption 3 does not apply to the individual at the
micro-level. It is 5. Interpretations of ParametersAll models
mentioned in this article are special cases of the
general model, formula The parameters of
this model will now be interpreted in light of the
theory in Statistically, ØjO^ describes the differentiation of the support for each party in time and space, while of0 deiscribes the general support (independent of subareas) for each party at each election. According to the theory, oi<D[h) is interpreted as the degree to which the image of party h at election t satisfies goals specific to the population of subarea i, while d^ is interpreted as the degree to which the image of party h at election t satisfies goals common to all subarea populations. 0{ is a vector describing the position of the specific goals of the subarea on different dimensions of orientation (e.g. manual-worker orientation, urban orientation), while O[h) is a vector describing the position of each party image at each election on these same dimensions. To sum up, these symbols have been given the following interpretations: ØP Orientation
vector of i:he specific goals of subarea i. Side 187
All models
described can now be interpreted as special cases of the
general model. model, formula
(16), it is evident that in this special case (20) that is, the orientation vector specific to the particular party does not change, whereas the satisfaction of common goals o^ for each party might change. This model provides a close fit with most of the parties in the Copenhagen data (see section 2 above). Similarly, when
the one-dimensional model for differential change,
formula (14), (21) that is, both orientation vectors can be described in one dimension. For the Copenhagen data, 6j was interpreted as manual-worker orientation on the basis of ecological correlation. Only minor changes were observed in 9^, the manual-worker orientation of the parties (see section 3 above). For the special
case of the multi-dimensional model for differential
change, (22) that is, the
parties can change in only one orientation dimension.
This dimension 6. ConclusionThe limited
Danish electoral data analyzed so far indicate that
simple models of I expect that models of this kind will find broad applicability in future electoral research. An important subject for further empirical and theoretical investigations will be the analysis and interpretation of the parameters estimated from the electoral data. Side 189
NOTES 1. Georg Rasch, 'A Mathematical Theory of Objectivity and Consequences for Model Construction', European Meeting on Statistics, Econometrics and Management Science, Amsterdam, 2—7 September 1968. 2. Ole Borre and Jan Stehouwer, Fire folketingsvalg, 1960—68, Århus: Akademisk Boghandel, 1970. 3. Borre and Stehouwer, op. cit. 4. Tage N. Bild, Om anvendelse af poissonmålingsmodellen, København: Københavns Universitets Sociologiske Institut. 1966 (mimeo). 5. Rasch, op. cit. 6. Søren Risbjerg Thomsen, Målingsmodeller for korttids-forandringer i vælgeradfærd, Århus: Institut for Statskundskab, Aarhus Universitet, 1971 (mimeo). 7. Thomsen, op. cit. 8. Ulf Christiansen and Jon Stene, 2. bind af G. RascKs lærebog i teoretisk statistik, København: Teknisk Forlag, 1969, Vol. 2, pp. 160-277. 9. Thomsen, op. cit. 10. Jan Stehouwer and Ole Borre, 'Four Elections in Denmark, 1960—68', Scandinavian Political Studies, Vol. 4, Oslo: Universitetsforlaget, 1969. 11. Thomsen, op.cit., section 7.7. approximately constant through the whole period.) 12. Stehouwer and Borre, op. cit. 13. Christiansen and Stene, loc. cit. Appendix 1This appendix
describes the computational procedure for the graphic
test of the model for For each subarea
at each election, the mean value of I{J° is computed
by arbitrarily
setting the mean values o°, a[-) equal to 0. We then
compute the difference From this
relation follows the relation where a dot
instead of an index indicates that the mean value is
computed for all values Appendix 2The first three
steps of the computational procedure for the
one-dimensional model for Christiansen and
Stene13 show a method of estimating the sign of 04 and
<p(h). With From these we can
get the stochastic relation: When r[J° is
plotted against r^ for each subarea, we get the graphs
in Figure 3, with |