Scandinavian Political Studies, Bind 1 (1966)NORWAY: THE STORTING ELECTION OF SEPTEMBER 1965Stein Rokkan and Torstein Hjellum Side 237
The election of
representatives to the Norwegian Storting on 12—13,
September 1965 Side 238
for four — one quarter more than for one. Under this formula, the average cost of M seats will approximate a limit 1.43 T as M increases: even in a nation-wide constituency the most expensive seats would not average more than one and a half times the cost of the threshold seats.3 The d'Hondt method had given the Labour Party a clear bonus in 1949: the party polled 45.7 per cent of the votes but gained a majority of 85 over 65. The Sainte formula reduced the överrepresentation but kept the party in power in the elections of 1953 and 1957. As will be seen in Table 1 the principal loser was the smallest of the parties, the Communists: they were unable to reach the threshold point in the great majority of constituencies and consequently wasted most of their votes. The first signs of a change in the majority — minority balance came in 1961: quarrels over foreign and military policy within the Labour Party had triggered the formation of a new party on the left flank and this new formation proved strong enough to break through the barrier in two constituencies. The Labour lead was cut down from 49.3 per cent to 46.8 per cent. If the d'Hondt procedure had still been in force, the party would have retained its majority. The Sainte-Lagué system produced a curious deadlock. Labour lost its majority but could not be ousted from power: the non-socialist Opposition could not muster a majority either and the parliamentary equilibrium hinged on the votes of the two members for the new Socialist People's Party. The crisis during the summer of 1963 herolded a decisive change in the balance of forces in Norwegian politics: the two Left Socialists voted against the Labour Government in August but allowed it to return to power after four weeks of government by the non-socialist coalition.4 The election of 12—13 September, 1965, broke this deadlocked 2—74—74 constellation: the Left Socialists stayed at the 2-member level but Labour lost 6 seats to the nonsocialist bloc. The changes in the actual voting strength of the two blocs were not as marked: the Socialist (CP + SP + Lab.) bloc lost 1.6 per cent of the valid votes but 4.0 per cent of the seats. The split in the Socialist ranks exerted a heavier toll in seats than in votes: an increasing number of votes were wasted on lists below the threshold of representation and the multi-seat Labour lists lost out in the fight with one-seat Opposition lists. Side 240
Table 2 shows the changes in the strength of the three Socialist parties and the non-socialist bloc from 1957 to 1965. The decline in the strength of the Communist Party continued throughout the period, but it can hardly explain the spectacular growth of the Left Socialists. The decline in the strength of the Labour Party from 1957 to 1965 was also marked, from 48.3 per cent to 43.2 per cent, but has to be weighed against the growth of the Left Socialists to the 6 per cent level. The total Socialist strength moved from 51.7 per cent in 1957 up to 52.1 per cent in 1961 and then back to 50.5 per cent in 1965^ If there had been a system of pure nation-wide PR the three Socialist parties would still have held a majority of seats in 1965, but the two leftist parties did not reach the threshold point in more than two constituencies and in this sense wasted most of their strength. The CP has been without representation in the Storting since 1961 and the Left Socialists were only able to cross the treshold in two constituencies with the largest numbers of seats: Oslo and Nordland. As a result, more than 11 per cent of the votes cast on the Socialist side in 1965 went without representation.5 By contrast the non-socialist parties wasted markedly fewer votes in 1965 than in earlier elections. Three weak lists had been withdrawn under a co-operative arrangement between the Christians and the Centre Party and the remaining belowthreshold lists from 1961 made a very good showing. The Liberals (Venstre) had seven lists below the threshold in 1961 but crossed it in four constituencies in 1965. The Centre Party, formerly the Agrarians, had three weak lists, gave up one and got in on the two others. The Conservatives (Høyre) were without representation in three constituencies in 1961 but made the threshold in all but one of them in 1965. The only loser in the non-socialist bloc was the Christian People's Party: it had presented unsuccessful lists in seven constituencies in 1961, withdrew two of these, but put up one new list without success and came below the threshold in one further constituency. The non-socialist parties won most of their victories on the thresholds to first seats. Four of the six Labour losses went to lists which had not reached the representation point in 1961: two to the Liberals in the Oslofjord area, one to the Conservatives in the West and one to the Center Party in the North. The other two losses were in the West: in these constituencies all the principal parties have crossed the threshold and the battle was waged over second seats. The overall gain in nonsocialist representation was the result of a double movement in the electorate: the Liberals gained ground in their below-threshold constituencies in the East while the Conservatives broke through toward full representation in their traditionally weakest territorities in the South and the West. To understand the processes at work in the 1965 election it is clearly essential to analyze the changes in the political balance between the regions in Norway. Table 2 gives a regional break-down of the figures for the two opposing party blocs, and Table 3 gives details about the parties in the victorious bloc of co-operating parties on the right. The well-established contrasts between East and West in Norway came out as clearly in 1965 as in 1957. The Socialist bloc stayed well above the majority point in the East, the Middle and the North, but dropped below the 40 per cent mark in the South and West.6 The Socialist losses were most marked in the Northern stronghold and much smaller in the four provinces (fylker) of the East Inland region: in these forestry-industry areas the working class parties still polled more than 60 per cent of the valid votes cast. No detailed ecological analysis of the variations in loss rates has as yet been carried out. Our first cross-tabulations by type of commune do indicate, however, that the Labour Party lost fewer votes in the fisheries districts and the least urbanized countryside than in the industrial areas and the cities.7 The Left Socialists made much more headway in the urbanized communes but the net losses for the three-party bloc were nevertheless heaviest in the cities. Further analysis suggests that the Socialist bloc held its own in the still mobilizing periphery, Side 242
the communes with the most marked increases in turnout, but lost out in the already highly politicized and polarized areas.8 The hypothesis we hope to explore in some detail in our analysis of the survey data collected before and after the election is that most of the changers in the economically advanced communities were younger, geographically and socially mobile voters: in these groups the rates of defection from traditional Labour loyalties seem to have been quite marked, mostly, it is true, toward the radical Socialist People's Party, but often also to the Liberals. Perhaps the single most important development in 1965 was the shift in the balance of electoral strengths on the non-socialist side. The Liberals had been losing ground in the Oslofjord region for. several decades but now suddenly came back in great force: the result was three hew mandates for a "middle" party in the most polarized of the regions. By contrast the Conservatives made heavy inroads in the typical "middle party" districts of the South and the West: there was a marked tendency toward continued polarization in the periphery but a reversal towards differentiated politics at the centre. This double movement helped the non-socialist bloc toward a clear victory in the battle for seats: they made their most significant gains in the constituencies where the pay-off was highest. There has been much speculation about the extent to which this was the result of "strategic voting": how many non-socialists defected from their traditional party to vote for a coalition list just below the threshold point? This raises tricky issues in analysis: we hope to be able to explore this in detail in our work with the survey data. The change-over to a coalition government of the four non-socialist parties prompted a great deal of speculation about the future of Norwegian politics: would the partners be able to work out an effective policy and agree on its implementation? Would they enter into closer co-operation and would two or more of them move towards full mergers? Would they even find it profitable to change the rules of the electoral game? This is not the place for a detailed discussion of trends in Norwegian politics: we shall confine ourselves to a quick review of the alternative reforms of electoral arrangements and their probable consequences for the distribution of seats among the parties. The basic structure of Norwegian electoral law is given in the Constitution: articles 50 to 53 give the qualifications for suffrage and articles 57 and 58 give the number of representatives for the country as a whole and for each of the 20 constituencies. Any change in the territorial structure of representation must be proposed during the first three sessions of one electoral period and must receive a two-thirds majority in the Storting established through the next election (article 112). The Storting elected in 1961 left a great variety of proposals for such changes for decision during 1965—69. Two concerns were dominant in these proposals: the preoccupation with strict nation-wide proportionality among parties and the claim for greater equality of representation among constituencies. Increases in the representation of the two central constituencies, the capital and the surrounding Akershus province, have been proposed again and again but all such initiatives have met with the old argument that the periphery deserves some överrepresentation in Parliament to offset the advantages of proximity to the decision-makers at the centre. The modest increases likely in the representation of Oslo and Akershus will not have any marked effect on the balance of forces in the Storting: Labour and the Conservatives will gain but the current 2—68—80 constellation will hardly be affected. The general proposal for the equalization of representation proposed by a Liberal leader9 seems likely to bring about a more pronounced polarization of the Storting the "middle" parties tend to be strongest in the currently overrepresented constituencies and would lose out against Labour and the Conservatives. Even more drastic changes are likely through the introduction of some form of cross-constituency representation: nation-wide members-at-large (utjevningsmandater på rikslister) or nation-wide Side 244
proportionalization of within-constituency allocations (utjevning ved omfordeling av sistemandater). In both cases everything will hinge on the threshold for participation in the final round of allocation: how many votes are required or how many direct seats? Table 4 sets out the consequences of three of the proposals and their alternative threshold provisions. The Liberal proposal has a great number of alternatives but none of them would keep out the smallest of the above-threshold parties from 1965: the strictest criteria are two direct seats or 4 per cent of the valid votes. The Socialist People's Party could claim 7 to 8 of the 11 additional seats to be allotted on a nation-wide basis and the non-socialist majority would .be considerably reduced. The Socialist People's Party has naturally supported this move towards nation-wide proportionality but has proposed a slight lowering of the second-round threshold: one direct seat or 3 per cent of the votes. A third proposal of some consequence has been advanced by Conservative members and represents an interesting novelty: there will be no additional seats but the allocation of the last seat in each of the 20 constituencies will be decided on the basis of the nation-wide results for the party, not the constituency results. The consequences of this procedure would again depend on the height of the barrier against minor parties. Several alternatives are offered. On the strictest criterion a party will only be allowed a share of the last seats in the twenty constituencies if it has gained three or more direct seats. This would exclude the Left Socialists from the round of "proportionalization" but nevertheless make for a tighter majority-minority constellation: 2—70—78. Under the mildest criterion only the Communists would be excluded and the Socialist People's Party would get 7 of the 20 last seats: this seems likely to bring about a 9—66—75 situation and a deadlock of the 1961 type. In sum, none of the proposed changes in the Constitution would improve the position of the non-socialist bloc and at least one of them might endanger it. Given the 1965 results, any government move to change the 1952 precedures could hardly be motivated by expectations of great gains for the non-socialist bloc: the most plausible motive would be the interest in offering further incentives for the maintenance of the split in the Socialist ranks. This objective might also be achieved through the lowering of the Sainte-Lagué threshold: this would not require a change in the Constitution but a simple majority decision in the Storting. Table 4 shows the consequences of two moves in this direction. At the 1.2 level the only change would be the transfer of one seat from Labour to the Christians. At the 1.0 level the Left Socialists would win two seats from the largest parties, one from Labour and one from the Conservatives. Of the government parties the Conservatives would benefit least from any such move: they have only one list below the threshold and would stand to lose in all the other constituencies. The coalition parties will clearly think twice before they make a move towards electoral reform. The Norwegian case offers fascinating evidence of the difficulties of national proportionalization in a system characterized by marked regional differences in party strength and clearly deserves further study in a comparative perspective. The Michelsen
Institute, Bergen Side 245
A 105,210 105,210
35,070 21,042 15,030 For any list already given one seat the next seat will cost (2M + 1)T— votes. The closer V is to (2M—1)T (the fewer the votes "wasted" in reaching M seats) the closer the increment required for one additional seat will approximate 2T+l (in this case 2 . 15042 + 1 = 30,085). The 1.4 barrier
thus adds two seats to the largest party: the two
smallest parties Side 246
NOTES 1 For detailed calculations of over-representation for different distributions of votes among parties see C.-G. Janson Mandattilldelning och regional röstfördelning. Stockholm, Idun, 1961. 4 For an analysis of the political situation prior to the 1965 election see S. Rokkan "Norway: Numerical Democracy and Corporate Pluralism" in R. A. Dahl ed. Political Oppositions in Western Democracies. New Haven, Yale University Press, 1966. 5 For detailed calculations see S. Rokkan and H. Valen "Stortingsvalget 1965 i søkelyset" Aschehougs Leksikonservice 4(4), 1965: 170—176. 6 For a detailed analysis of statistics through 1961 see S. Rokkan and H. Valen "Regional Contrasts in Norwegian politics", pp. 162—238 in E. Allardt & Y. Littunen eds. Cleavages, Ideologies and Party Systems. Helsinki, Westermarck Society, 1964. 7 S. Rokkan, H. Valen and A. Amundsen "Stortingsvalget 1965. Et første sett analyser av resultatene". Samtiden, 74(8) 1565: 463—480. 8 For a discussion of these concepts of electoral analysis, see S. Rokkan and H. Valen "The Mobilization of the Periphery" 'pp. 111—158 in S. Rokkan ed. Approaches to the Study of Political Participation. Bergen, Chr. Michelsen Institute, 1962, also S. Rokkan "Electoral Mobilization, Party Competition and National Integration", to be printed in J. LaPalombara and M. Weiner eds. Political Parties and Political Development. Princeton, Princeton University Press, 1966. 9 The texts of the alternative proposals are in "Grunnlovsforslag fremsatt på 108. ordentlige Storting" Dok. nr. 15 (1963—64). Oslo, Arnesen, 1964, pp. 13 sqq. |