Nationaløkonomisk Tidsskrift, Bind 130 (1992) Festskrift til Sven Danø og R Nørregaard Rasmussen (I)

On the Empirical Verification of the Purchasing Power Parity and the Uncovered Interest Rate Parity

Institute of Economics, University of Copenhagen

Katarina Juselius

Resumé

SUMMARY: The long-run foreign transmission effects are first analyzed in a system of Danish and German prices, exchange rates and interest rates. The results gives emperical of purchasing power parity between the countries as well as interest rate parity. The adjustment coefficients indicate that the prices do adjust although slowly but that the adjustment is primarily in the exchange rates. The deviations from these parities are used as determinants in the final econometric analysis of the determination of exchange prices and interest rates in Denmark. The final model provides empirical evidence on the strong dependence of the Danish economy on the West German prices and interest rates in particular after 1983 with the deregulation of capital movements.

1. Introduction

The determination of real exchange rates has been in the focus of interest in a vast number of empirically oriented papers, see for instance Adler and Lehman (1983), Baillie and Selover (1987), Corbae and Chilians (1988) and Schotman (1989). In Denmark recent contribution is Paldam (1988). A common feature of basically all empirical is the rejection of standard economic hypotheses. The final breakdown of the Bretton Woods system in 1972, with the suspension of the convertibility into gold, led to the float of the dollar and some other currencies. In Europe several countries (the group of 10) including Denmark decided to manage their exchange rates within the so called snake which later was followed by the EMS. The new more flexible system was generally expected to solve previous policy conflicts between maintaining either the external or the internal balance of the economy. In reality most economists were taken by surprise by the great volatility of the exchange rates. Today, approximately two decades Bretton Woods, one dare say that there is no real understanding why exchange behave as they do.

In this short paper we will discuss the possibility that previous shortcomings can to some degree be explained by "missing econometrics" and then illustrate the basic points using an analysis of the purchasing power parity (ppp) and the uncovered interest parity (uip) between Denmark and Germany.

Side 58

2. Economic background and the choice of econometric method

In an open economy the international link between the goods and the capital markets can be found in the determination of the exchange rates. The international transmission effects are usually analyzed in the goods market by assuming adjustment to purchasing power parity and in the capital markets by assuming market clearing based on uncovered rate parity.

The theoretical motivation for the ppp is based on the assumption that internationally goods are perfect substitutes for domestic goods. As a description of reality is clearly an oversimplification and the empirical verification of this hypothesis has generally been very poor (Dornbush, 1988). There are several reasons for this, among the more important can be mentioned, differences in tastes, technology, the relative of the tradable and nontradable sector between countries. These arguments that if the ppp mechanism is functioning at all, it must only be in a longrun i.e. as a tendency of the two markets to adjust toward this party. Empirical on ppp is therefore most likely to be found between countries of similar technological development with strong trade associations. These conditions seems to be approximately fulfilled for Denmark and West Germany. In fact, Schotman (1989) investigated the ppp hypothesis for 10 major OECD countries and found that these could be clustered into three groups of trading countries within which evidence of the ppp seemed to be supported by the data.

The uip hypothesis states that the interest rate differential between two countries is equal to the expected change in the exchange rates. The empirical verification of the uncovered interest rate parity as a market clearing mechanism has neither not been convincing. Because of this many authors have tried to explain the lack of fit with the existence of a risk premium. For instance Fisher et.al. (1990) found empirical support for the parity between UK treasury bill rate and Eurodollar rate when adding a risk premium by the balance of payments deficit relative to GNP.

But another possible explanation to the poor empirical support for both the uip and the ppp hypothesis might be found in "inadequate econometrics". It seems like most empirical works have failed to properly account for (i) the time-series properties of the data, (ii) the interaction between the goods and the capital markets and (Hi) different short-and long-run effects. These three points will be discussed below.

Most empirical works have not given the time-series properties of the data sufficient attention. This means that valuable information in the data has not been used as efficientlyas For instance, recent advances in the theory of nonstationary timeserieshave a powerful tool to discriminate between on one hand stationary and on the other hand nonstationary processes of different order and to determine those directions in which the nonstationary variables can be made stationary by linear combinations.These combinations determine the so-called cointegration relations,

Side 59

among which hypotheses about hypothetical long-run relations can be tested. Failure to
account for these important time-series properties of the data is likely to invalidate the
statistical inference.

The two parties have usually been investigated as isolated phenomena either in the goods or the capital market, without paying enough attention to the interactions between the two. As a consequence most empirical work on the ppp and the uip hypothesis has been done in a single equation framework and usually without reference to the rest of the economy. Under the assumptionthat the ppp is only valid in the long run, adjustment can a priori take place both in the prices of either country and in the exchange rates. In addition one can also expect information about ppp to be found in the interest rate equations. motivation is the following. Under assumption of sticky prices deviations from ppp are likely to have some persistence. This in turn will result in deficits in the trade balance, which will affect the capital account and hence lead to a pressure on the interest rates. Therefore one cannot exclude the possibility that interest rates react to deviations from the ppp. This means that information about the ppp and the uip can be found in the price equations, interest equations as well as in the exchange rate equation. Therefore single equation estimates are likely to be both biased and inefficient, and the ppp and the uip should consequently be analyzed in a system of equations.

Many studies derive the empirical model directly from a very restrictive hypothetical economic model. If in reality there are costly arbitrage, imperfect information, costly adjustment, etc., the short-run behavoiour can be very different from the long-run. In such cases one should be careful not to start with a two restrictive model, since that could easily deteriorate any inference on the how the markets work. In a macro-economic prices and interest rates are determined by the interplay of forces driving domestic and international markets. Both effects have to be accounted for in order to obtain a full understanding how these important variables react to different chocks in the economy. If the adjustment to ppp is very slow, as is indeed very likely, the relative weight of this term compared to other short-run effects is probably small. Moreover, if the short-run effects are basically different from the long-run effects, the explicit specification of the former becomes mandatory, even if the main empirical interest in the long-run relations.

The methodological implication of all this is that one should be careful with the usual paribus assumptions. The fact that economic theory is seldom unambiguous, or never omnipotent w.r.t. the economic reality, is the econometric motivation for starting a general model formulation. This leads us to formulate a model that does not directly impose the uip and/or the ppp restrictions but, more indirectly, assumes a tendency the market to react to deviations from these relations. These considerations motivate a model specification of the error-correction type (for an extended discussion, see Juselius, 1991 a):

Side 60

Prices


DIVL1229

(1)


DIVL1233

(2)

Exchange rates:


DIVL1239

(3)

Interest rates:


DIVL1245

(4)


DIVL1249

(5)

where p denotes prices, e denotes exchange rates, / denotes interest rates, a subscript' 1'
and '2' denotes Denmark and West Germany respectively, fm(AX) indicates a linear
function of AXt, AX,.U..., where Axmt is excluded and m =pup 2,p2, el2, i\, i2.

In the above formulation the backward adjustment to deviations from the ppp is described
the ppp error-correction mechanism:


DIVL1257

(6)

whereas the adjustment to the uncovered interest rate parity is not as straightforward in the above formulation and therefore requires some comments. If this parity holds exactly we would have that (ix- i2), = (Ae[2)ee t +\, where superscript e denotes expectation. future exchange rates are difficult to predict, one would expect the market to adjust in a backward looking manner to the realized deviation from this parity, namely to the uip error-correction machanism:


DIVL1263

(7)

In the above model formulation no restrictions on the coefficients of the short-run dynamics, fm(AX), are made. In particular, the coefficient ofAe]2t is not restricted according the ecmuip hypothesis. The motivation for this is that the inclusion of Ael2t unrestrictedly infm(AX) allows exchange rates to affect interest rates and prices also through other channels than the uip. Thus in the above form the model allows for other explanations in the short run but presumes ppp and uip to determine the long-run steady-state

Side 61

3. The statistical model

It was shown in Granger (1983) and Engle and Granger (1987) that an error-correction implies cointegration and vice versa. The rnultivariate cointegration model seems therefore to be a natural choice of statistical model for our empirical problem. This means that we can utilize the statistical distinction between stationary and nonstationary to analyze whether there exist stationary linear relations between the levels of the nonstationary variables (Johansen (1988), Johansen & Juselius (1990)), and if this is the case whether the unrestricted relations are consistent with the hypothetical long-run relations. The empirical multivariate cointegration model discussed below is given by:


DIVL1276

(8)

where zt = \_P\»Pi' e\i> h> h] *s defined above, z_, andz0 are fixed, e,,...,er are i.i.d Np(O,X)Np(0,X) and D, are centered seasonal dummies. All long-run information is contained in the levels component 77zM. Under the hypothesis thatz, is 1(1) and et is stationary it follows that the matrix U cannot be of full rank, since a stationary process Azt cannot equal something nonstationary. If on the other hand 77 = 0 the model is empirically consistent but there is no long-run information in the data and the model would be reduced to a standard VAR-mode\ in differences. The third possibility is that 77 is of reduced rank which is the hypothesis of cointegration formulated as 77= a(3' where a and /3 arepxr matrices. In this case j3'z, defines the cointegration relations, which often be given an interpretation as economic long-run relations, whereas a defines the weights with which these enter each of the equations Azjt. The properties of the I( 1) model can be summarized by noting that Az, is stationary, z, is nonstationary but /3'z, is stationary.

If however the (the appropriately transformed) matrix F, also is of reduced rank the vector prozess {z,} is second order nonstationary, implying that some (or all) of the variables zit are integrated of order two (see Johansen, 1992/)). In this case (3'z, is generally of order one, although under certain conditions it is possible to divide the r cointegrating relations into r-s stationary relations and s first order nonstationary relations, where s is the number of common trends integrated of order two in the system applications see Johansen, 1992 c and Juselius, 19926).

4. An empirical illustration

We have chosen to illustrate the ideas discussed above with a data set that describes how Danish consumer prices, interest rates and exchange rates are affected by what happens to German prices and interest rates. The empirical analysis can be seen as a complement and an extension to Juselius (1991 a) where the data are explained in more

Side 62

detail. Similar analyses have also been performed on other data sets, for instance on
UK data in Johansen and Juselius (1992) and Johansen (1992c).

The econometric procedure takes place in two steps: In the first step the long-run structure of the system is estimated and a priori hypotheses concerning long-run steady-states tested. In the second step the deviations from these steady-states are used as determinants in the analysis of the short-run structure.

4.1 The cointegration analysis

The multivariate cointegration analysis of this data set is thoroughly discussed in Juselius a) and we will here only discuss the 1(2) extension. The statistical analysis of (8) indicated that there are three cointegration relations and consequently two common When applying the recently developed 1(2) procedure (Johansen, 1992b) it was found that the process was integrated of order 2 and consequently that some of the variables are approximately integrated of order two. An extended discussion of the 1(2) analysis is however not possible within the present page restrictions. Therefore we will only informally discuss the additional information given by the 1(2) analysis. The interested is referred to Johansen (1992 c) and Juselius (19926).

The analysis revealed that the Danish and German consumer price variables could be classified as second order nonstationary processes, whereas the exchange rates and the interest rates were first order nonstationary. However the price differential px - p2p2 could be considered a first order nonstationary process, implying that prices are cointegrating 1(2) to 1(1). To illustrate the time series properties of the individual series they have been arranged below on a scale measuring the degree of integratedness:


DIVL1316

where {} denotes a time-series process. Since only the two price series are 1(2) one could of course do the cointegration analysis by replacing price levels with inflation rates the vector zt. This however would imply that some valuable information contained the levels would be lost and is therefore not a recommendable procedure. In table below the three cointegration vectors from Juselius (1991 a) are partitioned into the 1(0) and I( 1) space.

The two stationary vectors jß°, i=l,2, suggests that the real exchange rate, {P\~Pi~eu.i and the interest rate differential, {ix—ii} are stationary processes. This can be seen by taking appropriate linear combinations of the first two vectors, using the result that linear transformations of stationary processes preserve the stationarity property.The vector, which is first order nonstationary, is essentially a weighed averageof

Side 63

DIVL1318

Table 1. The cointegration vectors decomposed into the 1(0) and 1(1) directions.

rageofthe Danish and the German interest rate level, which indeed should be 1(1). As shown in Johansen (19926) the nonstationary )3-vector can be brought down to stationarityby linear combination, o>, of the differenced process, i.e. 0'zt + co'AzJ —l (0). As can be seen from Table 1 column a), the two inflation rates are primarily needed to obtain stationarity of /31 'zt,. This is intuitively an appealing result since it says that althoughnominal rates behave in nonstationary manner, real interest rates are in fact stationary.

Before moving to the analysis of the short-run effects the hypothesis that the real
exchange rate and the interest rate differential are contained in the cointegration space
will be formally tested as the hypothesis:


DIVL1308

where p is a 2 x 2 matrix and ifj is a 5 x 1 vector of unrestricted coefficients. This hypothesis be tested by a likelihood ratio test procedure described in Johansen and Juselius The test statistic became 1.70 and is asymptotically distributed as x2x2 (4)- Therefore the hypothesis was clearly accepted. In table 2 the restricted estimates are given.

The first vector is essentially describing the interest rate differential, the second vector
real exchange rate combined with the interest rate differential, and the third vector
nominal interest rate level given by the sum of two interest rates.

In the next section we will use the cointegration results from the restricted analysis
to estimate the short-run structure of the equation system (l)- discussed in section 2.
But since the German price and interest rates can be considered weakly exogenous

Side 64

4.2 The short-run structure


DIVL1330

Table 2. The estimated cointegration vectors under restriction (3 = {Hp,if/}.

The procedure we have followed here is to use the deviations from the long-run parities determinants to the short-run behaviour of exchange rates, interest rates and price The short-run effects are estimated using a "general to specific" data based In the first place the unrestricted short-run structure as given by (1) - (5) was estimated. By restricting insignifikant coefficients to zero and imposing other data consistent restrictions we arrived at the empirical models presented in Table 3.

We will now comment on the three equations in turn, starting with the model for the
exchange rates which is considered to be the most interesting of this study.

The exchange rate equation:

The estimated coefficients to the interest rate differential and the real exchange rate do seem to indicate that nominal exchange rates adjust to the assumed equilibrium states both the capital and the goods market. As expected the speed of adjustment is much faster to the interest rate differential than to the ppp. The interrelatedness of the two markets can be noticed from the fact that the adjustment to the ppp is prolonged when the interest rate differential is positive. This could be consistent with the fact that membership of the snake and presently the EMS has placed restrictions on the magnitude changes in the exchange rates. If prices are sticky, as is usually assumed, and the adjustment in them is not fast enough, interest rates have to perform some of the "work" to restore the external balance.

In addition to the two steady-state adjustment terms, nominal exchange rates seem to react quite strongly to short-run changes in the basic determinants. It is interesting to notice that a positive change in German real interest rate and a positive rate of change in the domestic interest rate both seem to lead to a depreciation in the short run. The estimated coefficients indicate however that the short-run effects are quite different from the long-run effects, and therefore illustrate the third point discussed in section 2,

Side 65

DIVL1342

Table 3. The estimated short-run structure for Aen ' Aix and Apl

namely the importance of allowing for a general specification, especially when shortrunand
effects are very different.

The interest rate equation:

In this case only the adjustment coefficient to the interest rate differential became significant. Combined with the significant coefficient to the current change in the exchange this is clearly an indication that interest rates adjust to a perceived discrepancy the uncovered interest rate parity. This can easily been seen by noting that .05^12,-. 10(7i- = - QSAex2t-.\o[(i\-i2)tA-Aenl\. Also in this case there are evidence of different short-run effects. The strong dependence of the German economy can be inferred from the fact that the Danish bond rate reacts primarily to changes in German interest rate and inflation rate.

The inflation equations:

Consistent with the assumption of sticky prices, the coefficient to the ppp is quite small but anyway significant, indicating that prices do adjust although slowly. The two interest rates in levels were included unrestrictedly in the first general model, but only the Danish rate was significant. On the whole, Danish inflation rate seems to follow the German inflation rate and reacts quite strongly to changes in the German interest rate. It adjusts to the ppp and is positively related to the level of the Danish bond rate. This is broadly consistent with the findings in Juselius (1992 a) where a larger set of determinants used in a more elaborate analysis of price inflation.

References

Adler, M. & B. Lehman. 1983. Deviations
from purchasing power parity in the long
run. Journal of Finance 38, 1471-1487.

Baillie, R. T. & D. D. Selover. 1987. Cointegration models of exchange rate determination. Journal of Forecasting 43-53.

Corbae, D. & S. Quliaris. 1988. Cointegration test of purchasing power parity. Review of Economics and Statistics 70, 508-511.

Dornbusch, R. 1989. Real Exchange Rates and Macroeconomics -A Selective Survey. Journal of Economics 91(2), 401-432.

Engle, R. F., D. F. Hendry & J-F. Richard.
1983. Exogeneity. Econometrica 51, 2,
277-304.

Engle, R. F. & C. W. Granger. 1987. Co-integration error correction; representation, and testing. Econometrica, 55, No. 2, 251-276.

Fisher, P. G., S. K. Tanna, D. S. Turner, K. F. Wallis & J. D. Whitley. 1990. Econometric of the Exchange Rate in Models of the U.K. Economy. The Economic Vol. 100, No. 403, 1230-1244.

Granger, C. W. J. 1983. Cointegrated Variables
Error Correcting Models, UCSD
Discussion Paper 83-13a.

Johansen, S. 1988. Statistical analysis of cointegration
Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control, Vol. 12., 231-254.

Johansen, S. 1991. Estimation and hypothesis testing of cointegration vectors in Gaussian autoregressive models. Econometrica, 59, No. 6, 1551-1581.

Johansen, S. 1992 a. Cointegration in partial systems and the efficiency of single equation To appear in Journal of Econometrics.

Johansen, S. 19926. A statistical analysis of
cointegration for 1(2) variables. To appear
in Econometric Theory.

Johansen, S. 1992c. An 1(2) cointegration
analysis of the purchasing power parity
between Australia and USA. To appear in

Colin Hargreaves (ed.): Macroeconomic
modelling ofthe long run. Aldershot.

Johansen, S. & K. Juselius. 1990. Maximum likelihood estimation and inference on cointegration with applications to the demand money. Oxford Bulletin of Economics Statistics.

Johansen, S. & K. Juselius. 1992. Testing structural hypotheses in a multivariate cointegration of the PPP and the UIP for UK. To appear in Journal of Econometrics.

Juselius, K. 1991a. Long-run relations in a well defined statistical model for the data generating process. Cointegration analysis of the PPP and UIP relations between Denmark and Germany. In Gruber, J. (ed.): Econometric Decision Models: New Methods of Modeling and Applications. Berlin.

Juselius, K. 1991b. On the design of experiments data are collected by passive observation. In Rosenqvist, G., K. Juselius, Nordstrom, J. Palmgren (eds.): A Spectrum of Statistical Thought. Essays in Statistical Theory, Economics and Population in Honour of Johan Fellman. och Samhålle, nr. 46, Skrifter utgivna vid Svenska Handelshogskolan,

Juselius, K. 1992a. Domestic and foreign effects on prices in an open economy. The case of Denmark. To appear in the Journal of Economic Policy Modeling.

Juselius, K. 1992b. On the duality between long-run relations and common trends in the 1(1) and the 1(2) case. An application to aggregate money holdings. To appear in Econometric Reviews.

Paldam, M. 1988. Den reale danske valutakurs DMk., Fmk., Nkr., Skr., FF, UK£, US$ og Yen 1950-1987. Discussion Paper 5, Institut of Economics, Aarhus University.

Schotman, P. 1989. Empirical studies on the behaviour of interest rates and exchange rates. Doctoral dissertation at the Erasmus University, Rotterdam.