Nationaløkonomisk Tidsskrift, Bind 107 (1969)

CONVERGENCE AND STABILITY IN THE NEOCLASSICAL GROWTH MODEL

HANS BREMS *

1. Introduction

In the neoclassical growth model entrepreneurs are assumed to produce a single good from labor and an immortal capital stock of that good. Thus investment is simply the act of setting aside part of output for installation as capital stock. Capital stock is the result of accumulated savings under an autonomously given propensity to save. Available labor force is growing autonomously, and there is always full employment.

Traditionally the one-good neoclassical growth model ignores the price of that good. But if one wants to examine the stability of neoclassical growth equilibrium, he will find price a convenient stabilizing variable. Let us, therefore, try to solve the neoclassical growth model for price and the proportionate of growth of price. In doing so we shall assume the money wage rate and its growth rate to be autonomously given.

2. Notation

Variables

C = consumption
9c = proportionate rate of growth of consumption C
gT = proportionate rate of growth of investment /
gL = proportionate rate of growth of employment L
gp = proportionate rate of growth of price P
Gs = proportionate rate of growth of capital stock S
gx = proportionate rate of growth of output X
gY = proportionate rate of growth of national money income Y
J = investment
y. = physical marginal productivity of capital stock



Professor, University of Illinois at Champaign-Urbana. The present article grew out of ray discussion Nationaløkonomisk Tidsskrift 1969, 107. bind, 1.-2. hefte, pp. 43-48 of Ølgaard's contribution to Udviklingslinjer i makroøkonomisk teori, eds. Niels Thygesen and P. Nørregaard Rasmussen, Copenhagen 1969.

Side 227

L = labor employed
P = price of good
R = revenue of entrepreneurs
S — capital stock of goods
\V = wage bill
X = output
Y = national moncy income
Z = profits

Parameters

et, (3 = parameters of production function
c = propensity to consume
F availablo labor force
9f = proportionale rate of growth of available labor force F
9m = proportionate rate of growth of multiplicative factor M
gw = proportionate rate of growth of money wage rate w
M — multiplicative factor in production function
w = money wage rate

For time coordinate we shall use t. The flow variables C, I, and X are measured in physical units consumed, invested, or produced, respectively, per annum of the good produced. All flow variables refer to the instantaneous rate of that variable measured on a per annum basis.

3. The Equations of the Model

To the seven variable growth rates listed in Sec. 2 apply the definition of a
proportionate rate of growth of a variable v as


DIVL5158

(1) through (7)

Define investment as the derivative of capital stock with respect to time:


DIVL5164

(8)

Let entrepreneurs apply the Cobb-Douglas production function


DIVL5170

(9)

where 0< a< 1, 0 < 0< 1, a + 0 = 1, and M > 0.

Side 228

Let profit maximization under pure competition equalize real wage rate
and physical marginal productivity of labor:


DIVL5178

(10)

Define the physical marginal productivity of capital as


DIVL5184

(11)

Define revenue as

(12)


DIVL5192

It follows from (12) applied to (11) that entrepreneurs will be earning
the profits

(13)


DIVL5198

Under full employment available labor force must equal labor employed:

(14)


DIVL5204

Define the wage bill as money wage rate times employment

(15)


DIVL5210

Define national money income as the sum of wage bill and profits bill

(16)


DIVL5216

Let consumption be a fixed proportion of output:

(17)


DIVL5222

where 0 < c< 1.

Output equilibrium requires output to equal the sum of consumption and
investment demand for it, or inventory would either accumulate or be
depleted. Thus

(18)


DIVL5230

Eqs. (1) through (18) contain the 18 variables listed in Sec. 2. Can we
solve such a nonlinear system?

Side 229

4. The Convergence of Neoclassical Growth Equilibrium

By the convergence of equilibrium we mean its tendency to settle down at
stationary proportionate rates of growth1.

Take the derivative of (9) and (14) with respect to time, divide the derivatives
(9) and (14), respectively, and find

(19)


DIVL5245

From the consumption function (17), the equilibrium requirement (18),
and the definitions (1) through (8) find

(20)


DIVL5251

Using (1) through (7), differentiate (20) with respect to time and find


DIVL5255

Insert (19) into this and express it


DIVL5259

(21)

Now there are three possibilities: If gs > gM/<x -f- gF then


DIVL5265

(22)

If

(23)


DIVL5273

then


DIVL5277

(24)

And if gs < gja + gF then


DIVL5283

(25)

We conclude that as long as gs is greater than the value (23), (22) shows
it to be falling. And as long as gs is equal to that value, (24) shows it to remainso.



1. The convergence of equilibrium should not be confused with the stability of equilibrium: Convergence no violation of any equilibrium condition, indeed all equations (1) through (18) remain satisfied throughout Sec. 4. A stability test necessarily involves such violation, as we shall see in Sees. 6-11.

Side 230

mainso.And as long as gs is less than that value, (25) shows it to be
rising.

Now gs cannot alternate around the value (24), for differential equations trace continuous time paths, so to get from a value on one side of (23) to a value on the other side, gs would have to pass through the value (23). But then (24) would keep it there.

Finally gs cannot converge toward anything else than the value (23), for if it did, then by letting enough time elapse we could make the left-hand side of (21) less than any arbitrarily assignable positive constant e, however without the same being possible for the right-hand side.

We have trapped gs, then: Either it equals f/w/« ~r 9f from the outset, or
if it does not, it will converge toward that value.

Insert (23) into (19) and find

(26)


DIVL5299

Once we have found gs and g^ we may guess the rest

(27)

(28)


DIVL5307

DIVL5309

(29)


DIVL5313

(30)


DIVL5317

To convince himself that those are indeed solutions, the reader should take derivatives with respect to time of Eqs. (8) through (10), (16) with (12) through (15) inserted into it, (17) and (18), use the definitions (1) through (7), insert solutions (23) and (26) through (30), and see that each equation is satisfied.

5. Equilibrium Price

At a particular time, the reader may wish to know, what is the equilibrium
level of price P? Use (10) to express P, use (9) to express LjX and to find
that


DIVL5330

Use (1) through (8), (17) and (18) to see that X/S = gsl(lgsl(l — c), then take
all this together and find the solution for equilibrium price to be

(31)


DIVL5336

where gs stands for (23).

6. Stability of Price Equilibrium

By stability of equilibrium we mean its ability to restore itself after a disturbance.
disturbance violates the output equilibrium condition (18), so let
us replace that condition by a definition of excess demand for output.

Side 231

(32)


DIVL5349

Initially D — 0, but now let price P change by dP. The effect of the change
upon excess demand is


DIVL5353

(33)

If we can show that (33) is negative, we have demonstrated that a price lower than equilibrium (dP -^ 0) will create positive excess demand, i.e. inventory depletion, and that a price higher than equilimiuiu uIP 0) will create negative excess demand, i.e. inventory accumulation. We have, m other words, shown equilibrium to be stable.

7. Two Asymmetries in Applying the Stability Test

Showing that (33) is negative will have to be done twice, once for dP < 0
and once for dP > 0. The reasons for this inconvenience are two fundamental
built into the neoclassical growth model.

The first asymmetry is that capital stock can rise but not fall. Once installed, stock is immortal, hence no cost is involved in using it. Furthermore, according to (9) and (11) the physical marginal productivity of capital stock is always positive. Consequently, no already installed unit of capital stock should be left idle. The second asymmetry is that at full employment, employment can fall but not rise.

8. The Desired Capital Intensity

The clue to the stability of the neoclassical growth model is its flexible capital intensity. Insert the production function (9) into the profit-maximization consequence (10) and find how a profit-maximizing entrepreneur's desired capital intensity responds to the real wage rate facing him:


DIVL5375

(34)

The elasticity of desired capital intensity with respect to the real wage
rate is, then, 1//3. The high elasticity for realistic values of /? is apparent
from Figure 1, drawn for aM = 1 and /? = 1/4.

9. Real Wage Rate Too High

First let us examine the disequilibrium case dP < 0. A lower price means a higher real wrage rate, which raises the desired capital intensity, i.e. induces capital deepening. Since the new higher real wage rate exceeds the physical marginal productivity of labor at full employment, entrepreneurs will accomplishtheir deepening by reducing employment L at constant

Side 232

DIVL5420

Figur 1

Side 233

capital stock S. The instant effect of the higher real wage rate, then, is a
negative excess demand in the labor market.

Of course, had the money wage rate w been a variable, such a negative excess demand would have reduced w until at the new lower price P the original real wage rate w/P had been restored. The inducement to capital deepening would then have been removed as suddenly as it arose, and the stability story would have ended. However, the money wage rate w was assumed to be a parameter, our numeraire if you like, so our story must go on In (34) keep -S constant, let L vary with P, and find


DIVL5390

(35)

Use (10) and (35) to find the effect of the new lower price P upon output
X, via employment L:


DIVL5396

(36)

Capital stock S remains as in equilibrium and grows as it did in equilibrium,
investment / must remain as in equilibrium:


DIVL5402

(37)

When output falls, consumption falls according to (17)


DIVL5408

(38)

Finally insert the derivatives (36) through(3B) into (33), use(l7), and find


DIVL5414

(39)

which is negative, so equilibrium is stable for dP < 0

10. Real Wage Rate Too Low

Is equilibrium also stable for dP > 0? In that case we collide head-on with
the inability of employment to rise and the inability of capital stock to fall,
as we shall now see.

A higher price means a lower real wage rate, which reduces the desired
capital intensity, i.e. induces capital shallowing. Since the new lower real
wage rate falls short of the physical marginal productivity of labor at full

Side 234

employment, entrepreneurs will try to accomplish their capital shallowing by raising employment L at constant capital stock S. The instant elTect of the lower real wage rate is a positive excess demand in the labor market. Again, had the money wage rate been a variable, it would have adjusted itself and restored the original real wage rate. But again, the money wage rate is our numeraire, hence the inducement to capital shallowing persists.

But how can one raise an already full employment? Instead, the capital
shallowing will have to be accomplished by reducing capital stock. In (34)
keep L constant, let S vary with P, and find


DIVL5434

(40)

Once installed, however, capital stock is immortal, and there is no cost involved in using it. Furthermore, according to (9) and (11) the physical marginal productivity of capital is always positive. Consequently, no already installed unit of capital stock should be left idle. When neither employment L nor capital stock S changes, output X will not change either:


DIVL5440

(41)

According to (17), consumption is unchanged if output is


DIVL5446

(42)

But what does change? How can the desired capital shallowing be accomplished? answer is that while no already installed unit of capital stock should be left idle, entrepreneurs are still perfectly free to reduce future capital stock by reducing investment.

The partial derivative (40) measures the change in desired capital stock brought about by, say, one cent's worth of price change. Such a change is small compared with a whole year's investment and may therefore be accomplished by changing the latter — remember that investment, like all flow variables, was said to be an instantaneous rate measured on a per annum basis. Consequently we may also think of the partial derivative (40) as measuring the change of a year's investment brought about by one cent's worth of price change:


DIVL5454

(43)

Finally insert the derivatives (41) through (43) into (33) and find:

Side 235

DIVL5460

(44)

(44) is negative, hence equilibrium is stable for dP > 0, too

11. Conclusion

Our stability test relied on the sensitivity of the desired capital intensity to the real wage rate. In this reliance the test admitted two possibilities. First the possibilitv that in order to accomplish capital deepening, firms may employ less than the availabip larmr force, liie possibility that in order to accomplish capital shallowing, firms may invest less than what is being saved.

But our stability test clearly recognized two impossibilities, both relevant to linns trying to accomplish capital shallowing. First the impossibility of raising an already full employment. Second the impossibility of leaving idle any already installed unit of capital stock.

We conclude that at a parametric money wage rate w, a variable price of goods P cannot for long deviate from its equilibrium level. Pushed off its equilibrium path by a wrong price, the system will correct that price. Once the price is back at its equilibrium level it will induce a capital intensity permitting firms once again to employ the available labor force and to invest what is being saved.